6. Extending social protection to informal workers

Universal social protection constitutes an essential component of the global agenda for sustainable development and is one of the key policy priorities in several regional and national commitments. Yet, the road to universal social protection remains difficult in many countries. One common challenge in most developing and emerging economies with a large informal economy is to remove the many legal, economic and institutional constraints that informal workers face in accessing social protection and to install funding mechanisms that are appropriate, fair, efficient and sustainable.

Evidence from KIIbIH data indicates that social protection coverage for workers is limited in most developing and emerging economies, although significant differences can be found across countries. The percentage of workers who benefit from social protection, either directly or indirectly through a household member, is lowest in countries in Africa and relatively higher in countries in Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC), Europe and Central Asia (ECA) and Asia (Figure 6.1).

African countries have relatively fewer resources to sustain social protection systems, and programme coverage is therefore lowest on this continent. In the ECA sample of countries included in the KIIbIH database, some form of social protection, such as mandatory privately funded pensions, is found in all countries. In many parts of Asia, social protection coverage is low, but countries provide a large mix of programmes, which results in high coverage estimates (see note below Figure 6.1). In LAC, social protection systems are generally well funded with a variety of programmes, ranging from insurance and cash transfers to other forms of protection.

Formal workers are better covered by social protection than informal workers are in most countries, according to KIIbIH estimates. More than 70% of formal workers across the surveyed countries benefit from or contribute to at least one of the following programmes: contributory pension, employment-based health insurance, programmes providing universal health coverage, unemployment insurance or unconditional/conditional cash transfers (hereafter, collectively constituting social protection coverage) (Figure 6.2). In comparison, only about 37% of informal workers benefit from one of these programmes. There are also large disparities across regions and countries. The coverage gap of informal workers is particularly significant among the sample of African countries, and is less pronounced in the sample of LAC, Asian, and ECA countries.

The large social protection gap between formal and informal workers mirrors, to a large extent, the coverage gap of informal workers with regard to contributory schemes. Formal workers benefit more often from contributory programmes (43.7%) than informal workers do (8.9%) (Figure 6.3). Most contributory schemes are traditionally employment based, and informal workers are usually unable to access them either because they are excluded from the scope of social security or because they are excluded from it in practice, due to the non-payment of contributions and lack of capacity to contribute to them, among other things. Yet, informal workers can (and, as evidenced, do) benefit from some contributory schemes, often on a voluntary basis, thanks to certain programmes1 that have eased barriers to participation for specific categories of informal workers, such as those who are self-employed.

In contrast, the coverage of non-contributory programmes across workers does not seem to be linked to their formal/informal status. This may reflect the fact that informal workers are more likely to receive lower pay or to live in poorer households, which would make them or their household eligible for means-tested social assistance programmes and are therefore more likely than formal workers to rely on government assistance (non-contributory programmes) to meet basic needs. Yet, the coverage non-contributory programme coverage varies depending on the country. In the sample of African countries, an average of 29.4% of formal workers and 17.2% of informal workers benefitted from non-contributory programmes; in the sample of Asian countries, an average of 62% of formal workers and 66% of informal workers benefitted from non-contributory programmes (Figure 6.4). The sample of countries from LAC is a notable exception, with the average non-contributory programme coverage for informal workers (33.1%) far outstripping the average coverage for formal workers (24.7%), probably reflecting the extension of cash transfers to poor households, which are more likely to be in the informal economy.

Social protection coverage tends to vary among the household income classes of informal workers,2 leaving a large segment of workers belonging to the near poor and middle-income categories largely uncovered. Contributory schemes tend to benefit relatively richer informal workers more than poorer ones, while non-contributory schemes typically benefit poorer informal workers rather than richer ones (Figure 6.5). Overall, in the sample of countries for which data are available, an average of only 5% of poor informal workers are covered by some type of contributory scheme compared with about 20% of more affluent informal workers. Likewise, about 39% of poor informal workers are covered by a non-contributory programme compared with nearly 31% of higher-earning informal workers.

Coverage levels also differ across countries. In the sample of countries from LAC and Asia, non-contributory programmes are targeted at the most vulnerable informal workers, whereas in the sample of African countries, affluent informal workers are more likely to be covered by both contributory and non-contributory schemes.

Informal workers also appear to benefit from different types of social protection when they live in rural rather than urban areas. Urban informal workers have better access to contributory programmes, but rural informal workers are better covered by non-contributory programmes (Figure 6.6). In two-thirds of the countries for which information is available, urban informal workers were more likely than rural informal workers to benefit from contributory programmes (Figure 6.6, Panel A).

In most countries (with the noticeable exception of the sample of African countries), rural informal workers reported better coverage by non-contributory schemes than urban informal workers did (Figure 6.6, Panel B). This is likely due to the long-standing disadvantage of rural areas with regard to access to services, infrastructure and information, and much of the rural labour force is precariously employed in agriculture. Not only is it harder to distribute and manage contributory schemes in rural areas but informing eligible participants about schemes can also be more difficult in rural areas than in urban areas. Cash or in-kind transfers are usually provided in rural areas to help households meet basic needs. This rural-urban difference in the type of social protection coverage may also reflect the higher prevalence of employees in urban areas and self-employed individuals in rural areas.

Access to social protection may also be influenced by whether informal workers hold citizenship in the country where they work. Using KIIbIH data, we find a relative disadvantage in accessing social protection between foreign-born informal workers and native-born informal workers. Compared with native-born informal workers, foreign-born informal workers are less likely to benefit from social protection. Such a gap does not seem to reflect a disadvantage in terms of contributory schemes, however. Since few informal workers have access to contributory schemes, the differences in contributory coverage between foreign-born informal and native-born informal workers tend to be small. Rather, the relative overall social protection disadvantage of foreign-born informal workers mirrors a gap in non-contributory schemes, which is particularly visible in countries where access to non-contributory schemes is more important. For instance, in China and Chile, foreign-born informal workers were about half as likely as native-born to benefit from non-contributory programmes.

The previous section documented the extensive gaps in social protection for informal workers. Social protection for informal workers will need to be based on a combination of contributory and non-contributory schemes. Country experiences show that very few countries have achieved both universal social protection coverage and adequate benefit levels by offering only one of these types of social protection. Universal social protection will most likely be achieved over time through progressive expansion, even if some countries have been successful in expanding their non-contributory schemes quickly, such as universal pensions or universal health coverage (ILO, 2018[2]).

Non-contributory schemes do not require contributions from individuals who benefit from social protection and are mostly financed directly from a government’s general budget – that is, from general taxation, non-tax revenue, or external grants or loans. There are many types of non-contributory programmes, such as universal schemes that benefit all individuals (e.g. a national health service), categorical schemes covering certain broad groups of the population (e.g. social pension or universal child benefit schemes) or social assistance schemes that provide benefits for groups of the population living in poverty (usually based on a means test, a proxy means test or other targeting mechanism).

Non-contributory schemes play a key role in ensuring a basic level of protection within the social protection system for poor and vulnerable groups who do not have access to contributory social protection. Non-contributory schemes are an essential component of any nationally defined social protection floor.

In many countries, reaching a consensus for using non-contributory, tax-financed programmes to reduce the social protection gap for the poor is often possible. It is therefore useful to assess the proportion of informal workers that could be covered through non-contributory programmes targeting the poor.

The extension of anti-poverty programmes would cover a large share of informal workers in many countries. According to KIIbIH data, and using international poverty lines for comparison purposes, around 86% of the informal workers in Zambia would be covered if anti-poverty programmes were successful in covering all informal workers who are poor (with a maximum daily income of int’l dollar 2.15/day), with similarly large proportions for Madagascar (75%) and India (71%) (Figure 6.7).

Yet, while a consensus for using non-contributory, tax-financed programmes to reduce the social protection gap for the poor may exist, in some countries this is not necessarily the case for informal workers who are not considered poor. In designing an approach to increase coverage for non-poor informal workers, countries face a host of difficult decisions, including whether to offer universal entitlements or use other coverage mechanisms, such as voluntary or mandatory public social insurance; how to develop processes for identification and enrolment of the non-poor; and how to create attractive social insurance schemes to collect voluntary contributions, and whether to subsidise contributory schemes.

According to KIIbIH data, more than one-half of children (60%) and older dependents (57%) live in households where all workers are informal (see also Chapter 5). This points to the key role that child benefits and social pensions could play as a supplementary mechanism to extend social protection to informal workers. If properly deisgned, these benefits could contribute to reducing the vulnerabilites that households with informal workers face.

Non-contributory social protection aimed at workers in the informal economy can play an important role. Emergency income support measures implemented during the COVID-19 pandemic showed that non-contributory social protection aimed at workers in the informal economy can play an important role in mitigating income risks. Brazil’s emergency income support programme, the Auxilio Emergencial (AE), showed the positive economic impact of incorporating informal workers into non-contributory income support programmes. The scheme was implemented in April 2020, with the benefit level set at BRL 600 (Brazilian reals) (int’l dollar 120) per worker initially, which later decreased in subsequent iterations. Importantly, the income threshold for access to the programme was raised to three times the minimum wage per household. As a result, millions of informal workers who lost their income because of restrictive measures adopted during the COVID-19 crisis gained access to the programme. Subsequent research has shown that this initial phase of the AE lifted 13 million Brazilians out of poverty and reduced inequality by offsetting poverty among Afro-descendant and indigenous people in the country (Lusting and Trasberg, 2021[3]).

South Africa’s COVID-19 Social Relief of Distress (SRD) Grant also initially incorporated informal workers. The South African government introduced the grant in April 2020. The eligibility criteria excluded those in formal employment, those aged under 18 years and over 59 years, those in receipt of any other grants or Unemployment Insurance Fund (UIF) benefits, and those in receipt of a stipend from the National Student Financial Aid Scheme (NSFAS). In this way, the SRD Grant partially addressed a large gap in the social security system by including those of working age in the informal economy. This iteration of the SRD Grant came to an end in April 2021 and was re-introduced subsequently with income threshold eligibility criteria which generally exclude informal workers. Research indicates that the initial design of the SRD Grant had positive economic impacts, including: (i) an increase in customer demand for the goods and services provided by informal traders, (ii) support for informal businesses, enabling them to survive in an environment of extreme economic stress and even to build businesses, and (iii) support for the circulation of people, goods and money, thus stimulating higher transaction intensity in different sectors and across value chains (Plagerson et al., 2023[4]). At ZAR 350 (South African rand) (int’l dollar 20 per month ) the SRD Grant was too small to reverse many of the negative impacts of the COVID-19 economic crisis, but it was assessed to have acted as an effective shock absorber, indicating the potential for such interventions to support informal workers and local economies over the longer term (Plagerson et al., 2023[4]).

Contributory social protection schemes constitute a key element of the extension of social protection to informal workers. Contributory schemes are based on the payment of contributions by workers and, in the case of employees, by their employers, which gives rise to acquired rights. As such, these schemes play an important role in the financing of social protection systems and can reduce the fiscal pressure on a government budget by offering a reliable and stable financing mechanism. Moreover, the level of protection offered by contributory schemes is usually higher than for many non-contributory schemes.

In most developing and emerging economies, contributory scheme coverage remains, by definition, limited to formal employees assuming a defined employment relationship based on a written contract and remunerated through regular wages, and with contributions typically shared between workers and employers. However, several contributory schemes also include other categories of workers, such as employers and own-account workers (ILO, 2021[5]).

A crucial step in the extension of contributory social insurance to informal workers has been the extension of social and labour rights to domestic workers through a combination of legal reforms and enforcement and simplification measures; the inclusion of self-employed workers in social insurance schemes through adapted mechanisms and simplified registration, tax and contribution payment mechanisms; the adaptation of contribution calculation and payment modalities to the capacities of workers and employers; and the use of digital and mobile technology to facilitate access to social protection.

As countries look at ways to extend contributory schemes to informal workers, they need to address several questions. One question is whether the extension of contributory schemes can be linked to an identifiable employment relationship between an employer and a dependent worker so that co-payments from the side of both employers and employees could presumably be an option. Another question is whether potential contributors may have the contributory capacity to enrol in contributory schemes. There is also the question about the extent to which the extension of contributory schemes can be best achieved through voluntary or mandatory enrolment.

Finally, in contexts where a significant number of informal workers live with formal workers and where transitions into and out of informal employment may take place, the extension of social insurance to informal workers through other household members who are formally employed and the portability of contributory schemes throughout the life cycle of workers need particular attention.

Status in employment is an instructive indicator for examining which actors should have responsibility for paying for the extension of social insurance to informal workers. As shown in Figure 6.8, a large share of informal workers in KIIbIH countries are own-account workers (39.0%) with no co-payment possibilities.3 However, another significant share of the informal worker population is composed of employees (32.5%) for whom co-payments from the side of both employers and employees could theoretically be a possible option.

Recent experiences with the development of social insurance schemes for informal workers show that affordability issues need specific attention in the design of such schemes. Therefore, looking at the individual contributory capacity of informal workers as well as that of their household is critical. As shown in Chapter 2, information on the level of earnings of informal workers within the country sample indicates that a large number of informal workers have low earnings. These workers may lack the contributory capacity to pay for social protection, and contributory schemes would either have to be subsidised by the government and/or complemented with employer contributions when possible. However, a significant proportion of informal workers – between 18% and 90%, depending on the country – have medium or high earnings. As a result, these informal workers may have some individual capacity to contribute to social insurance schemes.

The affordability of schemes for informal workers will also vary depending on their status in employment. A key issue for self-employed workers is the affordability of contributions. The fact that they do not have an employer who can share the cost means that self-employed workers are often required to contribute a higher share of their earnings to finance social insurance benefits. High contribution levels are particularly concerning, as many self-employed workers have low and often fluctuating incomes.

As a result, even when self-employed workers are legally entitled to access social insurance through voluntary or mandatory schemes, many of them are unable to afford contributions, which tend to be much higher – often twice as high – for self-employed workers than for employees (OECD, 2019[6]; OECD/ILO, 2019[7]). As Figure 6.9 shows, contributions from self-employed workers can often be higher than those paid by employees.

To improve the affordability of contributions for self-employed workers, governments have pursued a range of strategies, including enabling a gradual scaling up of contributions, providing matching subsidies, adjusting contributions to income levels and facilitating the settlement of arrears. In Algeria and Uruguay, the government allows new self-employed contributors to begin contributing at a lower rate and then gradually increasing to the standard tax rates that apply (ILO/FAO, 2021[9]; Aguiar et al., 2023[10]).

In several cases, governments have provided matching subsidies. For example, in Mongolia, the government matches contributions of herders and other informal and self-employed workers at 13.5% of their declared earnings. In Costa Rica, the government implements a proportional matching subsidy, with rates that vary with the income of the contributor and an inversely proportional schedule of subsidies. Mandatory health insurance for self-employed workers requires contributions of 11,00%, and mandatory pension insurance for self-employed workers requires contributions of 7.75%. However, only those with earnings of more than ten times the minimum wage pay the full amount. Those earning around half the minimum wage only pay 3.75% for health insurance and 4.25% towards their pension. Between those two categories, there are five earnings categories, set as multiples of the minimum wage. As incomes grow, workers pay higher contribution rates and government subsidies decrease, while the totals always remain at 11,00% and 7.75%.

Members of Thailand’s voluntary social security scheme for informal and self-employed workers (Social Security Fund Article 40) receive a contribution from the government, paid into their social security account. The government’s contribution increases with workers’ contributions. In the case of the most basic benefit package, workers pay a monthly contribution of THB 70 (Thai baht), complemented by THB 30 from the government. Those who opt into higher benefit packages pay THB 100 (with the government contributing THB 50) or THB 300 (with the government contributing THB 100) per month.

In Costa Rica and Mongolia, programmes to help self-employed workers settle social security arrears are likely to have helped bring back former contributors who had accumulated debt from periods when they had not made contributions. For example, in Costa Rica, the government has periodically implemented payment plans, moratoria and interest/fine cancellation, including following the COVID-19 crisis, when employers and self-employed workers were given 12 months to apply for cancellation of surcharges, interest and fines, which is expected to restore the rights of some 140 000 workers. In Mongolia, the Law on Repayment of Pension Insurance Premiums of Herders and Self-employed, implemented in 2020, enabled participants to settle arrears on favourable terms (including making back payments at a rate of 10% of the minimum wage). In Uruguay’s social Monotax, accounts are frozen if registrants miss two months of contributions, but no late-payment interest is charged. The registration can be reactivated by paying the delayed contributions.

However, reducing contributions to address affordability challenges can have negative implications in terms of their adequacy, especially if not paired with subsidies that raise contributions to a sufficiently high level. In the case of Uruguay’s Monotax, subsidised contribution rates enable low-income informal workers to access benefits that are limited when compared with those offered by the standard social security system. In particular, Monotax registrants note the low value of retirement benefits and occupational injury benefit. Members of Thailand’s Article 40 scheme for self-employed workers also perceived the value of their benefits to be inadequate, especially regarding the scheme’s sickness benefit and compared with the scope and quality of benefits offered to formal sector workers.

Low levels of adequacy appear to be a particular issue in stand-alone schemes for informal or self-employed workers when compared with countries where such workers can access the general social security system with rights and entitlements comparable to those of formal employees. ILO supervisory bodies have generally observed that schemes based on the capitalisation of individual savings fall short of International Labour Standards on Social Security, in particular the principles of solidarity, risk sharing and collective financing, as well as the predictability of benefit levels (ILO/WIEGO, 2023[11]).

The low and often fluctuating earnings of most informal workers mean that the integration of informal workers in schemes not based on the principles of solidarity, risk sharing and collective financing will likely result in inadequate benefits. A recent evaluation of Rwanda’s Ejo Heza long-term savings scheme highlights the challenges of achieving adequate pension levels for informal workers through voluntary savings schemes alone. The authors calculate that annual savings rates would have to increase by a factor of four to five – and be paid consistently for at least 25 years – in order to provide pensions equivalent to the poverty line for 240 months (Guven and Jain, 2023[12]). The capacity of general social insurance schemes to generate adequate and predictable benefits through solidarity, risk sharing and collective financing heightens the importance of reforms seeking to ensure their inclusiveness for informal workers.

The contributory capacity to enrol in contributory schemes may also depend on household income, at least for some specific schemes such as health insurance. Examining the income category of informal workers is therefore essential. Evidence from KIIbIH data suggests that some informal workers live in non-poor households. Of these “non-poor” informal workers, between 27.7% (Zambia) and 94.8% (Sierra Leone ) are in the middle or affluent class and could potentially be enrolled in non-subsidised contributory schemes if such schemes were available and/or enrolment compliance improved (Figure 6.7). Yet, between 8.8% (Zambia) and 50.4% (Uruguay) of informal workers are in the “near-poor” category and would most likely need to be supported through subsidised contributory schemes, as their contributory capacity to pay contributions on a regular basis may not be sufficient.

Remittances may also influence the contributory capacity of informal workers at the household level. They enable households to finance voluntary contributory schemes (Kolev and La, 2021[13]) and act as an informal insurance (Beuermann, Ruprah and Sierra, 2016[14]; Geng et al., 2018[15]). Relatively well-off recipient households may use the funds to participate in formal contributory schemes. In the case of Colombia, for instance, recent evidence shows that remittances are an important source of income that increases enrolment in contributory social insurance schemes among informal workers (Cuadros-Meñaca, 2020[16]). Moreover, remittance receipts can provide useful information to governments on the capacity of households to contribute to social insurance schemes such as health insurance.

An important question, therefore, is to what extent and under which conditions informal workers who receive remittances and who do not qualify for social assistance may be willing and able to channel some of their resources towards enrolling in formal social insurance schemes. According to KIIbIH data, 10.5% of informal workers live in a household that receives remittances and that is food secure (Figure 6.10). This suggests that the development of social insurance schemes targeting middle-class informal workers who receive remittances may be worthwhile.

Looking at the presence of formally employed workers in informal workers’ households can also yield useful information for the extension of social protection to informal workers. In principle, a small share of informal workers could benefit indirectly from the social protection coverage provided by formally working household members. One-quarter of informal workers live in households with other formal workers (so-called “mixed households”; 24.9%, Figure 6.11) and could presumably be covered indirectly by certain social protection schemes that they would not otherwise have access to (such as health insurance and old-age pensions). In LAC, for example, certain programmes like survivor pensions are paid for through contributions from the formal worker’s salary but can benefit any informal workers who were part of the household unit when the formal worker passed away.

Indirect access to social insurance through other formally working household members can be seen in, for example, health insurance coverage for informal workers. In a few countries, employment-based health insurance enables formal workers to add household members to their insurance plans, effectively covering them where they might not be entitled to any other insurance (Figure 6.12). According to KIIbIH data, health insurance coverage for informal workers in mixed households is higher than coverage for informal workers in informal households across many countries: for example, in Argentina, 59.2% of informal workers in mixed households benefitted from some form of employment-based health insurance coverage compared with 35,0% of informal workers in informal households. The findings are similar for Indonesia (7,0% in mixed and 2.6% in informal), Kyrgyzstan (44.3% in mixed and 33.2% in informal) and Namibia (10.1% in mixed households and 8.2% in informal households).

However, a social protection strategy based solely on the potential for informal workers to benefit from the coverage of formal workers may also come with some adverse incentives for formalisation and may not take into account the fact that informal workers tend to live only with other informal workers. Moreover, not all social protection programmes benefitting formal workers (contributory programmes) can be opened to other household members.

While this does not describe most of the workforce, some individuals tend to transition between status in employment and into and out of informal employment and the workforce (Chapter 3). As a result, provisions that allow workers to carry benefit entitlements across formal and informal forms of employment can reduce the likelihood that workers will lose their entitlement to social protection after transitioning to another job opportunity. Moreover, contributory social protection should be designed in such a way that it is able to manage workers’ fractional contribution histories and additional payments at one point in time, so that workers are able to obtain access to benefits that have been paid for through both contributory and non-contributory schemes.

Overall, these results confirm that countries do have opportunities to develop strategies to extend contributory social protection to informal sector workers, and that these strategies need to take specific challenges and constraints at the individual or household level into account. Aside from the barrier of affordability and co-payment possibilities, some informal workers may be living in a household that comprises only informal workers, whereas others may be living in a household where at least one of the members has a contract in the formal economy. Other challenges include the fact that some informal workers may face difficulties in meeting administrative requirements; other categories of informal workers may simply not be covered by the applicable legislation; or the social insurance schemes may not be adapted to the specific needs of informal workers in different work and household environments. Finally, when specific contributory schemes are made available to informal workers, the level of benefits may be considered too low to make the schemes attractive.

Despite these challenges, efforts by governments to expand contributory schemes to informal workers are gaining traction around the world. Lessons about what works to extend contributory social protection to informal workers can be learned from such attempts across a range of criteria, including affordability, attractiveness, access, awareness and association (ILO/WIEGO, 2023[11]). Table 6.1 provides a summary of ten short case studies collected by WIEGO and the ILO showcasing innovations in social insurance to better cover self-employed informal workers.

The affordability of schemes has been addressed by governments through several strategies, including a gradual increase in contributions for newly contributing workers; a reduction in contributions either by lowering the rates or removing a contribution and possibly by making contributions income dependent; providing matching subsidies; providing top-ups for care credits; and facilitating the settlement of arrears. However, lowering contributions as a single strategy may result in inadequate benefits so that the attractiveness of the scheme to workers is compromised.

Matching subsidies from the government can play an important role in ensuring the adequacy of benefits while maintaining affordability. Costa Rica’s Social Security Scheme ‘CCSS) provides progressive matching subsidies according to income levels in order to ensure greater inclusion of low-paid workers in the informal economy. Another less well-explored strategy is to derive co-contributions from economic actors other than employers within the value chains in which informal workers are embedded. For example, waste pickers in Argentina are exploring ways in which to leverage extended producer responsibility legislation in order to generate finance designed to improve working conditions and social protection coverage (Cappa et al., 2023[17]). In India, the same sector has been successful in making claims for social protection benefits from various actors in recycling value chains, including municipalities, citizens and businesses (Chikarmane and Narayanan, 2023[18]). Such co-responsibility for financing has also been observed in Portugal for “economically dependent” self-employed workers, which are workers who receive more than 50% of their income from one contracting entity, such as certain gig and platform workers.

Contributions and benefit levels across schemes should be designed to ensure that incentives towards underdeclaration of income, disguised employment and illicit registration are minimised. In Brazil, steep increases in contributions between the individual micro-entrepreneur regime, the monotax regime and the general tax regime, while social protection benefits remained similar across all three, meant that there was little incentive in place for businesses to increase contributions as they grew (ILO, 2019[19]). In 2018, the country implemented a new, progressive tax schedule to address this issue.

While the affordability of contributory schemes is an important consideration for low-income workers, this is not the sole barrier to uptake. The attractiveness of benefits is an important area for consideration in the design of contributory social protection. In Thailand, an ILO (2022[20]) study noted that contributions to the voluntary Article 40 Social Security Fund fell well within the average savings capacity of more than two-thirds of the working age population. Nonetheless, membership in the scheme remains much lower than the proportion of the population who should have sufficient savings capacity to participate. Qualitative investigation into perceptions of the Article 40 Social Security Fund among informal workers found that key reasons for the lack of uptake included the benefits not being considered sufficiently attractive, concerns about administrative barriers and a lack of knowledge about the scheme.

One common strategy is to combine long-term benefits (such as pensions) with short-term benefits in order to provide benefits that are immediately relevant. This combination was the case for all of the countries listed in Table 6.1, with old-age benefits most commonly combined with disability and survivors’ benefits. Maternity benefits and health insurance were also common short-term benefits, and in the case of Zambia, a weather index insurance was included in order to enhance the attractiveness of the benefits for small farmers.

Countries have also experimented with the inclusion of incentives aimed at MSEs in addition to a mix of social security benefits. In Cabo Verde, the Regime Especial das Micro e Pequenas Empresas (REMPE), or Special Regime for Micro and Small Companies, provides a favourable tax regime to MSEs, with a 30% reduction in taxes for the first year of membership and a 20% reduction during the second year. Subsidies for personal income tax (PIT), value added tax (VAT), fire tax and social security contributions (SSCs) for employees are also available.

Simplified registration and benefit claim procedures can be found in many countries as a strategy to improve access to contributory social protection. Brazil and Uruguay have implemented monotax schemes for specific groups of workers, where a single payment covers both tax and SSCs. See Box 6.2 for a more detailed discussion of business-related incentives in Uruguay. Brazil has also reduced the documentation requirements for registration and benefit claim procedures. Mongolia uses one-stop shops where workers can access a range of social security services, including mobile services for workers unable to travel and herders unable to leave their livestock.

Tunisia’s Ahmini (“Protect Me”) scheme – affiliated to the Caisse Nationale de Sécurité Sociale (CNSS), or National Social Security Fund – provides insights into how to effectively use innovative technology to improve access to contributory social protection and facilitate contribution collection. The scheme specifically targeted low-income women working in agriculture, drawing on partnerships with telecommunications enterprises to provide an online application and payment service to members. In order to enable greater accessibility in a context of low literacy, the application could also operate through voice activation. In addition, community volunteers and “ambassadors” supported the collection of documents and the distribution of social security cards to those unable to use the mobile technology. This highlights the importance of offering flexibility and choice, with both manual and online options in place for registration and benefit claims.

Self-employed workers are not necessarily well informed about their social protection rights and obligations, and they are often underrepresented in processes that determine social protection rights and entitlements. The two challenges, and the solutions to address them, are mutually reinforcing: raising awareness about social security often requires the active engagement of community members, and vice versa. Several case studies, notably Cabo Verde, facilitated awareness raising through carefully designed and targeted communications campaigns. Government actors in Mongolia, Tunisia and Zambia have engaged with workers’ organisations, and in Costa Rica, the use of collective insurance agreements stands out among the case studies as perhaps one of the most distinctive approaches to engaging self-employed workers and their representatives in the management of their schemes. For nearly 40 years, the CCSS in Costa Rica has enabled workers’ co-operatives to collect and transfer contributions on behalf of workers.

The design of extension strategies often hinges on two key issues: first, whether to make schemes mandatory or voluntary, and second, whether to integrate schemes for self-employed informal workers into mainstream social protection schemes or to develop them separately. On the first issue, the case studies presented here point towards mandatory coverage being more effective (Brazil, Cabo Verde, Costa Rica and Uruguay). Voluntary schemes in Mongolia and Thailand were less successful in expanding coverage. However, the case studies also offered some evidence that mediating factors – such as the type and quality of benefits on offer, the degree and type of enforcement, and the existence of incentives – also had an impact on whether schemes were successful or not. Moreover, in the most successful case studies, extension was integrated into a wider whole-of-government approach to reducing informal employment. Where participation is mandatory, it must be accompanied by adequate investment in enforcement, as well as affordability and accessibility.

On the second issue, the case studies presented here tended towards the incorporation of self-employed workers into mainstream schemes, rather than creating separate schemes. However, there was wide variety and nuance in these two approaches. In several countries (Algeria, Cabo Verde, Costa Rica, Mongolia and Portugal) where self-employed workers were incorporated into the general scheme, specific mechanisms were put in place to encourage access for the self-employed. Conversely, in Brazil, Thailand, Uruguay and Zambia, separate schemes were established with specific adaptations for the self-employed, but within the institutional framework of the general system. This suggests that the reality is more nuanced than simply choosing between integrating self-employed workers into mainstream or specific schemes.

Overall, across the case studies, the most common enabling factor was a strong institutional and governance framework. Strong institutions were cited in Algeria, Brazil, Costa Rica, Mongolia, Tunisia, and Uruguay, and were also significant factors in Cabo Verde and Portugal. After strong institutions, the legal and policy environment was highlighted as an important enabling factor in Brazil, Cabo Verde, Costa Rica, Tunisia, and Uruguay. Several of the case studies – specifically Brazil, Costa Rica, Mongolia, Portugal, and Uruguay – indicated high administrative capacity as a key enabler of success. Less frequently, but not less importantly, additional important enabling factors in each country included relatively high levels of trust in government or expressed willingness to contribute (Algeria and Zambia); the involvement of international actors (Mongolia and Zambia); and the strength of workers’ movements and organisations (Costa Rica). No single factor is sufficient to explain or enable success on its own, but rather worked in tandem with others, the strategies employed by governments and the idiosyncrasies of the unique historical, political, economic and institutional contexts and legacies of each country. But a combination of high institutional capacity, strong legal and policy frameworks, and high administrative capacity appeared to be powerful determinants of success in countries such as Brazil, Costa Rica and Uruguay.

Closing the global social protection coverage gap, including for informal workers, requires a step change in financing strategies. According to estimates from the ILO and the Overseas Development Institute (ODI), the funding gaps for social assistance alone, and excluding healthcare, range from USD 34 billion to USD 36 billion per year (United States dollars) for all low-income countries. As a result of the COVID-19 crisis, the ODI estimates that nearly all low-income countries and some lower-middle-income countries will not be able to afford even one-half of the required costs by 2030 (Evans et al., 2023[22]).

Designing the domestic social protection system in a way that encourages informal workers with some contributory capacity to contribute (for example, through the schemes discussed in the previous section) could be one way to mobilise revenues and finance the expansion of social protection.4 Supporting the inclusion of informal workers in social insurance schemes would not only provide higher levels of protection for previously excluded workers and their dependents, but also has the potential to increase their productivity and incomes through formalisation. However, even in the best-case scenario, the number of previously informal workers who register with the social security administration will only increase gradually. In order to achieve universal social protection, most governments will have to find strategies to mobilise significant tax revenue in addition to supporting the inclusion of informal workers in social insurance schemes. Additional tax revenue may be necessary to finance universal social protection floors or to design the type of contributory schemes that are both affordable and attractive and encourage informal workers to register.

High rates of informal employment suggest that relying mostly on the revenue generated from traditional contributory social insurance is not sufficient. As discussed in the previous section, few informal workers participate in contributory social protection schemes,5 which implies that these systems generate neither enough revenue nor adequate coverage for informal sector workers. Relying solely on SSCs to finance a universal healthcare system does not appear to be a recommendable strategy from efficiency and equity perspectives according to several academic studies (Yazbeck et al., 2020[23]). Countries with high rates of informal employment may opt to first establish or expand social protection floors through universal non-contributory schemes that are financed by general tax revenue, which can be supplemented with contributory social protection schemes. While this approach may result in limited protection initially due to low tax revenue it may be the only feasible option for some countries (especially low-income countries) in the short term.

Over time, countries that have chosen this path can gradually increase the generosity of their social protection floors when they are able to collect more tax revenue and/or start introducing contributory schemes that would finance social services above the minimum floors. Countries that have chosen to finance a large share of their social protection system through general tax revenue will have to ensure that all individuals pay their fair share of general taxes. A large informal sector makes it difficult to raise the general taxation revenue necessary to finance adequate universal social protection benefits for all; informal workers who do not pay SSCs will also not file a PIT return; and a large informal sector will reduce the potential revenues from VAT and other indirect taxes.

Other countries might be able to provide universal social protection floor by further redesigning the existing contributory and targeted non-contributory schemes and by expanding their coverage to those currently lacking coverage. This may be a viable strategy in, for instance, countries where SSCs are paid by employees but are not paid by self-employed entrepreneurs. The preferred strategy has to be evaluated at the country level and will depend on country-specific structural features and options for reform. The strategy will also need to be dynamic in that it can and should adjust and change over time.

Additional revenues will have to be raised primarily through the domestic tax system (including SSCs) in order to be sustainable in the long term. Indeed, only domestic government resources will provide the reliable stream of sizeable revenues that are independent from other countries’ priorities and necessary to sustain and further expand social protection over the medium and longer term.

Reprioritising government expenditure and increasing spending efficiency will not be sufficient to close the substantial social protection financing gaps that can be observed in developing countries (Figure 6.13). For instance, the social protection gap is estimated to be around 15% of gross domestic product (GDP) for low-income countries and 5% for lower-middle-income countries (Figure 6.13, Panel B). To close the gap, many low-income countries would have to spend more than 75% of their tax revenues on social protection (Figure 6.13, Panel A), more than the expenditure of OECD member countries with a much larger tax revenue base.

Lower-middle-income countries would need to spend around 50% of their current tax revenue on social protection alone, which will not be possible considering other pressing spending needs. Even though spending reallocation can be part of the strategy to close the social protection financing gap, it will not be sufficient on its own.

Raising additional general government revenue will be a key component of most countries’ strategies. The tax policy measures aimed at raising additional revenues need to be carefully chosen and accompanied by tax administration measures as well as by efforts to build a taxpayer culture. Tax measures implemented to close the social protection financing gap should ideally not harm other development goals (e.g. they should not place an additional burden on the poorest, or increase inequality) and should not come at the cost of other key development expenditure (such as on the education system).

The impact of tax measures on economic development and investment must be taken into account as well. Economic growth will be necessary to finance high-quality social protection in developing countries. In a context of low levels of GDP, mobilising a higher share of GDP in taxes to finance social protection will ultimately not be sufficient to finance high-quality social protection, especially in low-income countries. Take, for example, the average GDP per capita of a lower-middle-income country in 2021, which was around USD 2 500 per year. Even a tax-to-GDP ratio of 50% (i.e. around in monthly per capita tax revenues) would not be enough to finance high-quality healthcare, adequate pensions and other pillars of social protection in addition to other pressing spending needs (e.g. education and infrastructure) if the level of income does not change. Economic growth is therefore unavoidably part of a strategy to finance the expansion of social protection to the entire population in a developing and emerging economy. As a result, any tax and SSC reform that aims at raising funds to finance social protection should, as much as possible, avoid creating hurdles to economic growth. For instance, taxes that are generally less harmful to economic growth (such as property taxes and indirect taxes) may be preferred (IMF et al., 2016[27]).

A preliminary frontier analysis (which compares current tax revenues to the estimated tax revenue frontier given a country’s structural characteristics) reveals that there is significant room for increasing revenues in developing countries, even with the current level of income and informal employment. In low-income countries, the tax revenue frontier (i.e. the tax revenues attainable given a country’s structural characteristics) is 5% of GDP higher than current revenue. These additional tax revenues are even larger in lower-middle-income countries, where they reach 9% of GDP on average. However, the tax revenue potential differs greatly across regions and countries.

Even if the theoretical potential for revenue growth is high, evidence shows that raising 5% of GDP – far below the actual financing gap in most low- and lower-middle-income countries – in additional tax revenue over a decade will already be challenging. Over the 1999-2019 period, fewer than ten developing countries in the OECD Revenue Statistics database managed to increase their tax-to-GDP ratio by more than five percentage points (Figure 6.14). According to the International Monetary Fund (IMF), increasing the tax-to-GDP ratio by five percentage points over a decade is an ambitious but feasible target for most developing countries (Gaspar et al., 2019[28]). Raising significant amounts of additional tax revenue over time in ways that are aligned with inclusive and sustainable economic growth objectives will require a country-specific tax reform plan that is carefully developed, implemented, and sustained over time.

Preliminary OECD analysis shows that, in countries with high informal employment, the short-term revenue potential is largest for indirect taxes such as VAT or sales taxes. Indirect taxes have the advantage of having a broad (and relatively inelastic) tax base. But increasing rates or broadening the base of indirect taxes to finance universal protection may increase the tax burden for the poorest members of society and could ultimately also have a negative impact on the size of the formal economy (by fostering the expansion of goods sold in the informal market). Recent evidence shows that, in some developing countries, poorer households mainly shop in informal markets, and thus consumption taxes are paid disproportionately by richer households, which offers an equity motive for relatively higher consumption taxes (Bachas, Gadenne and Jensen, 2020[29]). However, if the poorest members of society are not able to afford to pay the tax when they do consume (even a small fraction of their total expenditure) in the formal market, it would be an inadequate tool with which to finance universal social protection floors. Thus, the “affordability” of indirect taxes needs to be assessed with care depending on the country characteristics. One strategy to increase government revenue which limits the negative impact on the poor could be to decrease or abolish reduced VAT rates or VAT exemptions applied to non-essential goods and use the revenue to expand social protection programmes targeted at the poor. Tax expenditure reports typically show that the tax revenues forgone from reduced VAT rates and VAT exemptions are large in developing countries. Lastly, the paper trail generated by a VAT system leads to the fact that a greater enforcement of regulation upstream or downstream implies a higher probability of being formal (Ulyssea, 2020[30]).

Health taxes, environmental taxes, fossil subsidy reform and tax expenditure reform are frequently included in the list of tax measures that can contribute towards raising more revenue for social protection in developing countries. Health taxes and environmental taxes or subsidies are mentioned in the context of social protection financing because of their direct link with health and social protection. However, the link does not imply that tax revenue from these sources would automatically be earmarked for social protection expenditure (as is the case with SSCs). The advantages and disadvantages of earmarking these tax revenues would have to be discussed in their own right. Options for tax expenditure reform can be identified by analysing the forgone revenue and the effectiveness and distributional impact of the tax relief provisions in place in each country. Priority shall be given to reform tax expenditures that are ineffective at achieving their goal. For example, certain tax incentives have been shown to have a limited impact on attracting investment or fostering growth (IMF et al., 2015[31]). It is also important to consider the distributional impact of tax expenditures. Income tax expenditures are often regressive and benefit high-income households disproportionately, which may constitute a rationale for reform.

Due to high informal employment and a lack of information and enforcement in low- and middle-income countries, third-best tax policies (such as taxes on inputs and turnover, which are usually not recommended in OECD member countries) need to be considered and evaluated in low- and lower-middle-income countries (Kleven, Khan and Kaul, 2016[32]). Ideally, the tax rate for each type of tax should be set at (or just below) the revenue-maximising tax rate. This revenue-maximising tax rate can grow over time by limiting tax evasion behaviour through better tax enforcement (Bergeron, Tourek and Weigel, 2023[33]).

For each tax type, it is important to evaluate, at the country level, whether there is a potential to: i) increase compliance, ii) limit international leakages, iii) broaden the tax base and avoid domestic leakages, or iv) increase the rate or introduce a new tax. It is also key to evaluate the revenue potential of each tax measure. Such an analysis, at the country level, would be part of the four modules of the new Social Protection Tax Revenue framework (Box 6.4).

In the context of high levels of informal employment, choosing the most suitable tax revenue sources involves additional trade-offs that need to be carefully balanced, including the challenge that the tax measures should not further hamper the employability of workers. Despite the more nuanced perspectives on informal employment that proliferate (see Box 6.3), fostering formal employment and the employability of the workforce continues to be an important task for developing countries. Many countries have large informal economies where workers are trapped in low-quality jobs without opportunities to upskill and grow into more productive jobs that potentially also provide for better social protection. Informal employment makes workers and their families vulnerable to economic shocks and adverse life events. Mobilising revenues to enhance social protection and using the available resources in the most effective manner needs to go hand in hand with policies that increase the number of informal workers who enter the formal economy and, indeed, policies that stimulate sustainable economic growth and formal work.

OECD member countries with comprehensive social protection systems tend to rely mainly on direct taxes and SSCs to finance social protection (Figure 6.15). SSCs account for around one-quarter of total tax revenue, and income taxes (corporate income tax (CIT) and PIT) for more than one-third. SSCs are taxes that are earmarked to finance social protection and, in many cases, there is a link between contributions made and benefits received (e.g. unemployment benefits, pensions). In a setting where taxpayers perceive SSCs as payments to themselves, either in the future or as an insurance, they may be more willing to comply with their tax obligations. This line of reasoning offers a strong argument for keeping SSCs in the social protection financing mix (instead of relying predominantly on PIT or indirect taxes to finance social protection, for instance). Maintaining a balance between employee and employer contributions is also desirable.

Most developing countries will likely eventually have to reorient their social protection financing towards SSCs. SSCs continue to play a key role in ensuring a basic level of protection, according to the ILO. One way to gradually increase revenue generation through SSCs could be to introduce presumptive tax regimes. Under such a regime, small businesses could be allowed to pay one single tax that replaces as many taxes as possible, including SSCs. The collecting body would redistribute the funds internally among the various institutions, including tax administrations and social security funds (Mas-Montserrat et al., 2023[34]).

Despite persistent informal employment, revenue raised through social insurance contributions has remained stable or even increased since the early 2000s and represent a major source of financing for social protection systems. Globally, SSCs accounted for 18.8% of total taxation or 5.7% of GDP in 2019 (for countries included in the OECD Revenue Statistics Database). In 2019, high-income countries raised on average 8.6% of GDP and 24.9% of total taxation via SSCs. Percentages were lower but still substantive for upper-middle-income countries (3.3% of GDP and 15.7% of total taxation), lower-middle-income countries (2.6% of GDP and 10.6% of total taxation) and low-income countries (1.3% of GDP and 8.1% of total taxation). From 2000 to 2019, SSCs as a share of GDP increased by 0.7 percentage points globally. Perhaps contrary to expectations, social insurance contributions as a percentage of GDP increased more in regions with higher levels of informal employment, such as LAC, Africa and Asia, albeit from a lower base (Calligaro and Cetrangolo, 2023[35]).

Replacing SSCs with PIT in developing countries that already rely partly on SSCs is therefore often not an appropriate strategy. Countries that struggle to raise revenues via SSCs face similar challenges when raising PIT given that it is a similar tax base (Figure 6.15). Abolishing employer SSCs would result in a significant reduction in tax revenue in many middle-income countries. The assumption that there will be full compensation and that wage levels will increase by the amount that employer social contributions were reduced, is also strong if the perceived link between contributions and benefits is low (Korkeamäki and Uusitalo, 2009[36]; Kugler and Kugler, 2009[37]; Bozio, Breda and Grenet, 2019[38]).

Voluntary private contributions can be complementary, but on their own (even if matched) they will fail to deliver universal and adequate social protection. Voluntary subsidised contributions have been suggested as a strategy to boost pension savings from the informal “missed middle” who are neither covered by contributory schemes nor receive universal benefits targeted at the poor (World Bank, 2019[39]). Examples of country experiences in which voluntary private schemes, on their own, managed to achieve universal and adequate social protection do not exist because social protection systems feature a redistributive component and are put in place precisely to address failures of private markets (such as adverse selection and externalities).

As mentioned in the previous section, the introduction of presumptive tax regimes has been one tool with which to gradually increase the coverage of non-standard workers in contributory schemes while at the same time raising some revenue and supporting formalisation. Presumptive tax regimes are often seen as a formalisation tool for enabling small businesses and self-employed workers to gradually become fully formal. However, badly designed regimes may have the unintended effect of discouraging businesses from growing in order to avoid sharp tax increases once they are subject to standard CIT or PIT, and may also encourage self-employment (Melguizo, Bosch and Pages, 2017[40]). Recent work by the OECD Centre for Tax Policy and Administration presents an analytical framework that characterises country-specific presumptive tax regimes and identifies best practices for the design and administration of such regimes (Mas-Montserrat et al., 2023[34]).

The impacts of social protection systems on labour markets with high levels of informal employment remain a concern for some policy makers at the international and national level. Existing evidence, however, does not necessarily support claims that social protection causes informal employment (Box 6.3). While the impact of social insurance contributions and payroll taxes is also a concern,6 studies have found mixed results. Reviewing the existing literature on the impacts of reduced or subsidised social insurance contributions on labour markets, Calligaro and Cetrangolo (2023[35]) showed that most studies found no significant employment effect.7 In his extensive review of the literature on informal employment, Ulyssea (Ulyssea, 2020[30]) reported that reducing the tax burden can induce some formalisation, although the elasticity seems to be low. The results depend on the relative level of SSCs compared with the productivity of workers in the economy and are therefore country specific. But experiences of countries cutting contribution rates – as part of structural reforms of pension or tax systems, during stabilisation programmes, and during crises, or to support the labour market participation of specific groups – have generally been disappointing in terms of generating formal employment, but have generated significant costs (Calligaro and Cetrangolo, 2023[35]).

Indeed, the fiscal cost of diminishing contribution rates might be sizeable. For instance, Egebark and Kaunitz (2013[41]) studied the payroll tax cut for young workers in Sweden in 2007-09 and estimated the cost per created job by comparing the cost of forgone payroll tax revenues due to the tax reduction with the increased tax revenues generated by the estimated employment and wage increases. The authors claim that the cost for each new job that was created was more than four times that of directly hiring workers at the average wage. More generally, any reduction in social insurance contributions creates an effective loss in government revenue in the short term. (Ulyssea, 2020[30]) concludes that reducing the costs of formality, in particular related to tax, has significant formalisation effects, but in general is not strong enough to be cost-effective, and has very limited aggregate effects.

Increasing tax compliance and enforcement can also be an effective strategy to increase tax revenues for social protection. Evidence shows that taxes are often evaded by misreporting economic activities that are difficult for the government to observe. Improved information collection and information sharing combined with better enforcement can thus increase revenue collection. Increased enforcement efforts are not limited to enterprises and can be complementary to adjusting tax rates in raising tax revenues from individual taxes (Bergeron, Tourek and Weigel, 2023[33]). Several concrete strategies to increase tax compliance have been identified in the literature. Some experiments show that in-person visits and training on formalisation induce enterprises to formalise and can increase government revenue if the interventions are sufficiently well targeted. Using third-party information reports to assist taxpayers in meeting their tax return filing obligations could also allow governments to increase tax revenues, eventually fostering formal employment (Kleven, Khan and Kaul, 2016[32]). Evidence also shows that implementing simple and objective performance-based pay incentive schemes for tax collectors could bridge wider enforcement gaps and help deliver increased tax revenues for the government. Finally, simplifying procedures, e-filing and providing reminders can help levy more revenue when tax evasion is related to a lack of knowledge about when or how to pay the taxes owed (Cohen, 2020[55]). Whether any of these strategies is applicable would have to be assessed at the country level.

Building a taxpaying culture is a crucial prerequisite for mobilising more revenue. Tax systems generally rely on the voluntary compliance of taxpayers (OECD, 2019[56]; OECD, 2022[57]). Although tax audits, fines8 and third-party reporting can increase tax compliance, tax administration resources are limited, especially in developing countries. Fostering tax morale (i.e. the intrinsic motivation to pay taxes) can play a key role in achieving significant revenue mobilisation. Work by the OECD shows that higher tax morale can typically be linked to taxpayers believing the tax revenues is spent effectively. Combining tax reforms with efficient and effective government spending allows countries to initiate a virtuous cycle of better-quality social protection services and higher tax revenues.

All of these dimensions are taken into account in the OECD Social Protection Tax Revenue (SPTR) framework, a country-specific tool that provides useful guidance in developing a tax reform roadmap for any country (Box 6.4).

Overall, the evidence presented in this chapter shows that in most developing countries, social protection coverage for workers is often inconsistent and sparse. Formal workers are also better covered by social protection than informal workers, which largely mirrors a coverage gap in contributory schemes and the way informal workers are defined. Extending social protection to informal workers is possible, however. A strategy to extend social protection to informal workers will need to be based on a combination of contributory and non-contributory schemes and incentives to formalise. It will also require a step change in financing strategies.

Non-contributory schemes play a key role in ensuring a basic level of protection within the social protection system. In nearly all developing countries, the extension of social assistance programmes for the poor would cover a large share of informal workers. Extending child benefits and social pensions could also largely benefit workers in the informal economy and their families.

Contributory social protection schemes constitute a key element of the extension of social protection to informal workers. A key challenge to the extension of contributory schemes to informal workers is that a large cohort of such workers do not have co-payment possibilities, and their contributory capacity appears limited overall. The affordability of schemes is particularly challenging for self-employed workers who cannot share the costs. Yet, the scope for employer-employee contributions can be significant for many informal workers, and some of them have contributory capacity at the individual or household level. Moreover, various options exist to improve the affordability of contributions. In addition, for certain types of contributory schemes, such as healthcare or pension schemes, a small share of informal workers could also be covered through formally employed household members.

Closing the global social protection coverage gap, including for informal workers, will require a step change in financing strategies. Reprioritising government expenditure and increasing spending efficiency will not be sufficient to close the substantial social protection financing gaps that can be observed in developing countries, and additional revenues will have to be raised primarily through the domestic tax system. Sustainably funded social protection systems are challenging to build when the level of informal employment is high, but several options exist. Although developing countries will have to mobilise significant additional revenues to finance universal social protection, significant potential exists to increase tax revenue in developing countries, including through well-designed SSCs. Careful tax reforms are needed in order to identify the most suitable tax revenue sources, and tax compliance and enforcement will have to play an important role.

References

[21] Abramo, L. (2022), Policies to address the challenges of existing and new forms of informality in Latin America, ECLAC, https://repositorio.cepal.org/server/api/core/bitstreams/431aed2d-2e7a-4f05-a942-b2d12db14bb5/content.

[10] Aguiar, S. et al. (2023), Monotributo y Monotributo Social en Uruguay: Apreciaciones de trabajadores y trabajadoras monotributistas, WIEGO and ILO, http://wcmsq3.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---americas/---ro-lima/---sro-santiago/documents/publication/wcms_890780.pdf.

[51] Alonso-Ortiz, J. and J. Leal (2018), “Cross-Subsidies, and the Elasticity of Informality to Social Expenditures: The Case of Mexico’s Seguro Popular”, Review of Income and Wealth, Vol. 64/2, pp. 482–512, https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/abs/10.1111/roiw.12284.

[44] Aterido, R., M. Hallward-Driemeier and C. Pagés (2011), Does Expanding Health Insurance Beyond Formal-Sector Workers Encourage Informality?: Measuring the Impact of Mexico’s Seguro Popular, https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-5785.

[53] Azuara, O. and I. Marinescu (2013), “Informality and the expansion of social protection programs: Evidence from Mexico”, Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 32/5, pp. 938–950, https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/S0167629613000982.

[29] Bachas, P., L. Gadenne and A. Jensen (2020), “Informality, Consumption Taxes and Redistribution”, NBER Working Paper, No. 27429, http://www.nber.org/papers/w27429.

[54] Barros, R. (2009), Wealthier but Not Much Healthier: Effects of a Health Insurance Program for the Poor in Mexico, https://ideas.repec.org/p/sip/dpaper/09-002.html.

[33] Bergeron, A., G. Tourek and J. Weigel (2023), “The State Capacity Ceiling on Tax Rates: Evidence from Randomized Tax Abatements in the DRC”, NBER Working Paper, No. 31685, http://www.nber.org/papers/w31685.

[14] Beuermann, D., I. Ruprah and R. Sierra (2016), “Do remittances help smooth consumption during health shocks?: Evidence from Jamaica”, The Journal of Developing Areas, Vol. 50/3, pp. 1-19, https://doi.org/10.1353/jda.2016.0098.

[45] Bosch, M. and R. Campos-Vazquez (2014), “The Trade-Offs of Welfare Policies in Labor Markets with Informal Jobs: The Case of the “Seguro Popular” Program in Mexico”, American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, Vol. 6/4, pp. 71-99, https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/pol.6.4.7.

[38] Bozio, A., T. Breda and J. Grenet (2019), “Does Tax-Benefit Linkage Matter for the Incidence of Social Security Contributions?”, IZA Discussion Papers 12502.

[35] Calligaro, F. and O. Cetrangolo (2023), Financing Universal Social Protection: The Relevance and Labour Market Impacts of Social Security Contributions, https://www.wiego.org/sites/default/files/publications/file/financing-universal-social-protection_0.pdf.

[52] Campos-Vazquez, R. and M. Knox (2013), “Social Protection Programs and Employment. The Case of Mexico’s Seguro Popular Program”, Economıa mexicana nueva epoca, Vol. 22/2, https://www.scielo.org.mx/pdf/emne/v22n2/v22n2a7.pdf.

[17] Cappa, A. et al. (2023), Efforts of Argentina’s Informal Waste Pickers to Finance Decent Work and Social Protection through Extended Producer Responsibility Legislation, https://www.wiego.org/sites/default/files/publications/file/wiego-resource-document-34.pdf.

[18] Chikarmane, P. and L. Narayanan (2023), Pune Waste Pickers’ Innovative Efforts to Fund the Extension of Decent Work and Social Protection, https://www.wiego.org/sites/default/files/publications/file/wiego-resource-document-33_0.pdf.

[55] Cohen, I. (2020), “Low-Cost Tax Capacity: A Randomized Evaluation with the Uganda Revenue Authority”, Working paper.

[16] Cuadros-Meñaca, A. (2020), “Remittances, health insurance, and pension contributions: Evidence from Colombia”, World Development, Vol. 127 (104766), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2019.104766.

[26] Durán Valverde, F. et al. (2020), “Financing gaps in social protection”, ILO Working Paper, No. 14, https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---ed_protect/---soc_sec/documents/publication/wcms_758705.pdf.

[41] Egebark, J. and N. Kaunitz (2013), Do payroll tax cuts raise youth employment?, Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN), https://www.ifau.se/en/Research/Publications/Working-papers/2013/Do-payroll-tax-cuts-raise-youth-employment/.

[22] Evans, M. et al. (2023), inancing social assistance in lower-income countries post-Covid-19: An exploration of realistic options, https://cdn.odi.org/media/documents/ODI_Financing_social_assistance_3iGJg6P.pdf.

[50] Galiani, S., P. Gertler and R. Bando (2014), “Non-Contributory Pensions”, Labour Economics, Vol. 38, pp. 47-58, https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0927537115001219?via%3Dihub.

[28] Gaspar, V. et al. (2019), “Fiscal Policy and Development: Human, Social, and Physical Investments for the SDGs”, IMF Staff Discussion Notes, No. 2019/003, International Monetary Fund.

[15] Geng, X. et al. (2018), “Health insurance, a friend in need? Impacts of formal insurance and crowding out of informal insurance”, World Development, Vol. 111, pp. 196-210, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.07.004.

[12] Guven, M. and H. Jain (2023), The Promise of Ejo Heza: A Brighter Future for All Rwandans, World Bank, https://documents1.worldbank.org/curated/en/099033123085036654/pdf/P1765760d02a820c109c3a076b3730e68cb.pdf.

[20] ILO (2022), Protection in Practice, Challenges and perceptions of domestic workers accessing social protection in Thailand, https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---asia/---ro-bangkok/documents/publication/wcms_878419.pdf.

[5] ILO (2021), Extending Social Security to Self-Employed Workers: Lessons from International Experience, https://www.social-protection.org/gimi/RessourcePDF.action?id=55728.

[24] ILO (2021), World Social Protection Report 2020–22: Social Protection at the Crossroads ‒ in Pursuit of a Better Future, International Labour Office, Geneva.

[19] ILO (2019), Simples National: Monotax Regime for own-Account Workers, Micro and Small Entrepreneurs: Experiences from Brazil, https://www.ilo.org/empent/Publications/WCMS_715864/lang--en/index.htm.

[2] ILO (2018), Social Protection for older persons. Policy trends and statistics 2017-19.

[9] ILO/FAO (2021), Extending Social Protection to Rural Populations: Perspectives for a Common FAO and ILO Approach, https://www.social-protection.org/gimi/RessourcePDF.action?id=57189.

[11] ILO/WIEGO (2023), Expanding coverage or reducing protection? Considerations on Voluntary Savings Schemes in Jordan’s social protection system, https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---arabstates/---ro-beirut/documents/publication/wcms_862452.pdf.

[47] IMF (2021), The Global Informal Workforce: Priorities for Inclusive Growth, https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/Books/Issues/2021/09/22/The-Global-Informal-Workforce-49719.

[27] IMF et al. (2016), “Enhancing the Effectiveness of External Support in Building Tax Capacity in Developing Countries”, Prepared for Submission to G20 Finance Ministers.

[31] IMF et al. (2015), “Options for Low Income Countries’ Effective and Efficient”, https://www.imf.org/external/np/g20/pdf/101515.pdf.

[49] Juarez, L. (2008), Are Informal Workers Compensated for the Lack of Fringe Benefits? Free Health Care as an Instrument for Formality, https://ideas.repec.org/p/cie/wpaper/0804.html.

[32] Kleven, H., A. Khan and U. Kaul (2016), “Growth brief: Taxing to develop - When ’third-best’ is best”, IGC Growth brief.

[13] Kolev, A. and J. La (2021), “Financing the extension of social insurance to informal economy workers : The role of remittances”, OECD Development Centre Working Papers, No. 344, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/bbc70a07-en.

[36] Korkeamäki, O. and R. Uusitalo (2009), “Employment and Wage Effects of a Payroll-Tax Cut—Evidence From a Regional Experiment”, International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 16, pp. 753–772.

[37] Kugler, A. and M. Kugler (2009), “Labor Market Effects of Payroll Taxes in Developing Countries: Evidence from Colombia”, Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 57(2), pp. 335-358.

[46] Levy, S. (2008), Good Intentions, Bad Outcomes: Social Policy, Informality, and Economic Growth in Mexico, Brookings Institution Press, https://www.brookings.edu/book/good-intentions-bad-outcomes/.

[60] Londoño-Vélez, J. and J. Ávila-Mahecha (2021), “Enforcing Wealth Taxes in the Developing World: Quasi-experimental Evidence from Colombia”, American Economic Review: Insights, Vol. 3/2, pp. 131-48, https://doi.org/10.1257/aeri.20200319.

[3] Lusting, N. and M. Trasberg (2021), “How Brazil and Mexico Diverged on Social Protection in the Pandemic”, Current History, Vol. 120/823, pp. 57–63, https://doi.org/10.1525/curh.2021.120.823.57.

[34] Mas-Montserrat, M. et al. (2023), “The Design of Presumptive Tax Regimes”, OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 59, https://doi.org/10.1787/141239bb-en.

[40] Melguizo, A., M. Bosch and C. Pages (2017), “Better Pensions, Better Jobs: Status and Alternatives Toward Universal Pension Coverage in Latin America and the Caribbean”, Journal of Pension Economics & Finance, Vol. 16/2, https://doi.org/10.1017/S1474747215000190.

[25] OECD (2022), Revenue Statistics 2022: The Impact of COVID-19 on OECD Tax Revenues, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/8a691b03-en.

[57] OECD (2022), Tax Morale II: Building Trust between Tax Administrations and Large Businesses, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/7587f25c-en.

[1] OECD (2021), Key Indicators of Informality based on Individuals and their Household (KIIbIH) database, https://www.oecd.org/dev/key-indicators-informality-individuals-household-kiibih.htm (accessed on 9 June 2021).

[6] OECD (2019), OECD Employment Outlook: The Future of Work, OECD Publishing, https://doi.org/10.1787/9ee00155-en.

[56] OECD (2019), Tax Morale I: What Drives People and Businesses to Pay Tax?, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/f3d8ea10-en.

[7] OECD/ILO (2019), Tackling Vulnerability in the Informal Economy, Development Centre Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/939b7bcd-en.

[58] Packard, T. et al. (2019), Protecting All: Risk Sharing for a Diverse and Diversifying World of Work. Human Development Perspectives, https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/entities/publication/5a09ca98-f1a7-5289-b2e6-7e06c63b0391.

[4] Plagerson, S. et al. (2023), “The local economic development effects of income transfers in South Africa. The Social Relief of Distress grant”, Working Paper, Agence française de développement, https://ideas.repec.org/p/avg/wpaper/en15333.html.

[43] Seira, E. et al. (2023), Did Mexico’s Seguro Popular Universal Health Coverage Programme Really Reduce Formal Jobs?, https://www.wiego.org/sites/default/files/publications/file/wiego-working-paper-no46.pdf.

[30] Ulyssea, G. (2020), “Informality: Causes dans Consequences for development”, Annual Review of Economics, Vol. 12, pp. 525-546.

[48] UNDP (2021), Regional Human Development Report 2021. Trapped: High Inequality and Low Growth in Latin America and the Caribbean, https://www.undp.org/latin-america/regional-human-development-report-2021.

[42] Wagstaff, A. and W. Manachotphong (2012), “Universal Health Care and Informal Labor Markets: The Case of Thailand”, Policy Research Working Paper, No. 6116, World Bank, Washington, DC, http://hdl.handle.net/10986/11940.

[8] WIEGO/ILO (Forthcoming), Inclusive social insurance – exploring real solutions to reach the self-employed.

[59] World Bank (2022), Charting a Course Towards Universal Social Protection: Resilience, Equity, and Opportunity for All. World Bank, https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/entities/publication/84ba2380-624c-553a-b929-2882e72c7468.

[39] World Bank (2019), World Development Report 2019: The Changing Nature of Work, World Bank, Washington, DC, https://doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-1328-3.

[23] Yazbeck, A. et al. (2020), The case against labor-tax-financed social health insurance for low-and low-middle-income countries, Project HOPE, https://doi.org/10.1377/hlthaff.2019.00874.

Notes

← 1. For example, monotax schemes and others. Further discussion to follow later in the chapter.

← 2. Depending on the country, income status used for this report is based on either household income or household consumption.

← 3. Co-payment could actually be a possibility for some informal workers classified as own-account workers who may indeed be dependent contractors according to the new ILO definition of employment.

← 4. The potential to increase financing of social protection systems through more inclusive social insurance systems is recognised by the Joint Statement on the Principles for Financing Universal Social Protection issued by the Global Partnership for Universal Social Protection to Achieve the Sustainable Development Goals (USP2030), which suggests that countries should seek to “increase revenues from social insurance contributions by expanding coverage of social insurance schemes to previously uncovered workers.”

← 5. The few informal workers covered through contributory schemes are mostly self-employed persons who opt for voluntary contributions, or persons covered by their spouses (see the previous section).

← 6. (Packard et al., 2019[58]) assert that social insurance contributions and payroll taxes have a negative impact on formal sector employment” (p. 207). Similarly, the World Bank expresses its concerns that contributions present a “risk of creating incentives for workers to remain in the informal sector” (World Bank, 2022[59]).

← 7. Of the 16 empirical studies reviewed, 10 find no impact and the others observe an increase in formal employment (1 finds increases only for older women).

← 8. Or, on the contrary, amnesty programmes for evaders (Londoño-Vélez and Ávila-Mahecha, 2021[60]).

Legal and rights

This document, as well as any data and map included herein, are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. Extracts from publications may be subject to additional disclaimers, which are set out in the complete version of the publication, available at the link provided.

© OECD 2024

The use of this work, whether digital or print, is governed by the Terms and Conditions to be found at https://www.oecd.org/termsandconditions.