7. Multi-level governance and co-ordination mechanisms to support regional attractiveness

Regional attractiveness is a multi-dimensional phenomenon that depends on a high number of actors. The OECD’s methodology considers more than 50 indicators to develop regional attractiveness profiles, covering 14 dimensions of attractiveness, across 6 domains (economic attraction, connectedness, visitor appeal, natural environment, resident well-being, land use and housing). As such, attractiveness policy is a “policy of policies”. The cross-cutting nature of the regional attractiveness paradigm means effective design and implementation of strategies to enhance it will have to bring together a multitude of actors, from different sectors (infrastructure, education, housing, industry, etc.), from different levels of government (local, regional, national) and different types of organisations (private, public, academia, civil society, etc.).

Multi-level governance is the way that responsibility is spread vertically among different tiers of government and horizontally across multiple administrations and non-governmental actors. It characterises actors’ relationships of mutual dependence and thus calls for and requires effective co-ordination. Without co-ordination at the right level, attractiveness policies risk generating negative externalities for other territories, zero-sum competition between territories, missing out on potential economies of scale and scope, or increasing territorial disparities. This can make regional attractiveness unlikely to be inclusive and sustainable overall. In this work stream, co-ordination concerns the management of cross-cutting issues that go beyond the frontiers of traditional policy sectors and administrative organisations and require coherent policy responses across scales. This surpasses the basic exchange of information among autonomous organisations. Rather, it involves the use of co-ordination mechanisms. These are initiatives governments introduce to facilitate joint, participative decision making and the pooling of resources to achieve collective policy goals that encompass – and exceed – the priorities of individual actors or agencies (McNamara, 2012[1]).

Regardless of the institutional context, regions are typically in a privileged position to design and implement attractiveness and retention policies, including by co-ordinating the relevant stakeholders. First, regions are at the intersection of national and local levels of government and close to businesses and civil society. In addition, key attractiveness policies, such as economic development and infrastructure, depend on competencies which are largely and increasingly allocated to their level of government (OECD/UCLG, 2022[2]). With the right capacities and institutional quality, they can play the role of a “hub” in the complex network of multi-level and multi-sector co-ordination necessary to design and implement effective attractiveness policies. Regional attractiveness policies do not only require synchronous co-ordination between different actors. They also require adjustment over time, based on the impacts of evolving megatrends such as the digital transition, climate and demographic changes and in some cases external shocks. They also require monitoring and evaluation, through economic, social and environmental indicators that measure their impact on attractiveness but also on inclusive and resilient regional development at large.

According to subsidiarity principles, a degree of independence should be guaranteed to a lower authority when a policy decision only impacts its local constituencies. Therefore, attractiveness policies cannot only depend on municipal decisions. First, because the strong attractiveness of one locality can lead to negative externalities such as congestion, consumption of natural resources or pollution, which risk negatively affecting neighbouring territories. Second, the strong attractiveness of one territory can also open opportunities to enhance the attractiveness of neighbouring territories by providing access to a dynamic local job market, good quality public services and infrastructure, etc. Therefore overall, local authorities should not compete but rather take a broader regional perspective and work together to avoid negatively impacting each other and better promote their region and the complementarity of their own assets. However, exploiting potential synergies between different parts of the same region is rarely a spontaneous process and requires appropriate incentives for co-operation to take place at the relevant scale; abundant literature can be quoted about inter-municipal co-operation or urban-rural linkages (OECD, 2023[3]; 2023[4]; forthcoming[5]). With regard to regional attractiveness, it is important to emphasise the key role of metropolises as engines for regional attractiveness and the need to identify appropriate ways to ensure that their success can benefit surrounding areas. The more attractive these large urban areas are to talent and visitors, the less affordable housing often becomes for inhabitants and newcomers. The scarcity of (affordable) land in metropolitan areas is also an obstacle to investment attraction in manufacturing. Developing partnerships with less dense peripheral areas – contributing to improving their connectedness with transport and digital infrastructure and containing any harmful impacts on the environment – can create mutual benefits and enhance the attractiveness of the region as a whole.

Regional authorities can play an active role in enabling regional synergies, as observed in this OECD project on rethinking regional attractiveness. In many Spanish regions, the regional government has taken steps to strengthen horizontal co-ordination through the creation of a second level of local administration (inter-municipal bodies called comarcas). In Cantabria, the reform provides for the creation of a total of ten comarcas, associating several municipalities with the aim of providing adequate and cost-effective public services in the region (OECD, 2023[6]). Some regional governments work to address disparities between large urban areas and territories at their periphery, for example the metropolitan area of Lisbon and the Tagus Valley in Portugal (OECD, 2023[7]), the Eastern and Midland Region in Ireland, which includes the Dublin metropolitan area, as well as the Mid-East and Midland Regions – parts of which form part of the Dublin functional urban area (FUA). While the Mid-East forms part of what is deemed the “core region”, benefitting from spillovers from Dublin (of investment, talent and visitors), the Midland Region is not benefitting at all from the diffusion of economic activity from Dublin and thus comes as one of the regions in Europe with the highest development trap intensity – which is surprising in what has been by some margin the most dynamic country in the European Union (Diemer et al., 2022[8]).

The Regional Spatial and Economic Strategy (RSES), co-ordinated by the Regional Assembly, outlines how collaboration among regional and local authorities, and across the border with Northern Ireland, can transform the Midland Region into a “gateway”, well connected to the rest of Ireland’s regions and Northern Ireland via the Dublin-Belfast Corridor. The co-ordinating role regions can play is also well exemplified in relation to attracting visitors, who, being mobile, can benefit several municipalities within a region. Such an approach is, for instance, adopted by the region of Algarve in Portugal, which uses the popularity of the city of Faro as a destination to promote its hinterland to visitors (OECD, 2023[9]). Similarly, the Valencian Community region in Spain intends to complement and attenuate the attractiveness of its “sol y playa” (sun and beach) assets with a variety of cultural and environmental amenities in currently lesser-known areas of the region (OECD, 2023[10]). Moreover, many regional government partners to this project also actively help harmonise infrastructure and services across local borders and prevent fragmentation of investments and projects, such as those linked to European Union funds.

The subsidiarity argument also justifies allocating attractiveness competencies to the regional level in the context of active co-operation with the central/federal level. While the macro drivers that significantly attract investors, talent and visitors are not region-specific (such as security for private investment, national labour and environmental regulations, customs; large infrastructure networks, etc.), regional competencies relevant to the development of attractiveness continue to increase. Indeed, about two-thirds of countries globally have increased the power of regions over the last 50 years (OECD, 2022[11]), in many cases including responsibility for the delivery of core services and infrastructure, many of which play a central role in regional attractiveness such as education, social protection, health, economic development or the environment (OECD/UCLG, 2022[2]). In Sweden for instance, since 2019, the 21 regions with elected regional councils, traditionally responsible for health and social services, have been devolved additional responsibilities for regional development and thus attractiveness. Through Ireland’s Local Government Act of 2014, the three Irish Regional Assemblies were established to deliver a regional and spatial economic strategy that outlines a core vision and long-term strategy for the territory, which cover a wide range of attractiveness objectives.

Regional authorities are highly involved in the processes of building attractive regions and are at the right scale to bring together relevant stakeholders in cross-cutting working teams that can break down sectoral and policy silos, agree on strategic directions and draft effective attractiveness strategies for the benefit of all. Regions are thus generally in charge of proposing regional strategies for inclusive and sustainable development (resulting from consultations of local and non-governmental partners) that serve as a prioritisation tool for co-funded investment (e.g. with national government and/or supported by European funds). The regional commitment is also a powerful guarantee of continuity in the action in favour of attractiveness and inclusive development – as exemplified by the case of Wales in the United Kingdom (Box 7.1).

Regional-level co-ordination facilitates the participation of subnational partners from public, private and civil society organisations (CSOs) in regional attractiveness policies. Because of their competencies and proximity to citizens, regions – more so than national actors – can build relations with those non-governmental actors that provide services essential to attracting and retaining mobile targets (real estate operators, language schools, banks, CSOs, etc.). For example, under the smart specialisation strategy (S3), the regional authorities of Centro, Portugal, encourage the creation of collaborative laboratories at the local level and a regional mobilisation programme to promote interaction between business associations and higher education institutions (OECD, 2023[15]). In the Swedish county of Norrbotten, under the North Sweden Green Deal co-ordinated at the regional level, the local University (Luleå University of Technology), various municipalities and the local destination management organisation (Swedish Lapland Visitors Board) work together to enhance the attractiveness of the region (OECD, 2023[16]). In France, the Industrial Territories policy (Territoires d’industrie) aims to strengthen the inclusive and sustainable reindustrialisation of specific territories by mobilising national, regional and local stakeholders including from the private sector. Its governance is based on a local, elected official-industry pairing, with steering by the regions together with active support from the state (OECD, 2023[17]). The regional level presents opportunities for the development of dynamic debates, trust-building and the evolution of reciprocal working relationships between centres and peripheries and among public and private stakeholders. If policy responses are to offer long-term regional resilience, they must also take into account the evolving preferences of target groups. Regions also need the tools and capacity to do so (surveys, public consultations, polls, etc.).

Regional-level co-ordination is important to develop digital platforms and physical one-stop-shops that offer information and guidance to talent and investors at all stages of the arrival process. Finland’s national Talent Boost strategy, for instance, largely relies on regions becoming official “talent hubs”. This co-operation service model is based on regions co-ordinating various sectors and actors including municipalities, employers, non-profit associations and universities, in order to create simple paths to help international talent settle and integrate into Finnish life. Onboarding websites and one-stop-shops offer a soft landing for companies and individuals who can quickly focus on non-administrative issues and help promote the territories they cover in an integrated and cohesive manner. Moreover, the Strategic Development Plan of the Special Economic Zone in Campania, Italy, has simplified administrative measures by introducing a digital one-stop-shop, facilitating access to information for prospective investors and obliging all stakeholders to co-ordinate in the back-office building of this tool (OECD, 2023[18]). Such platforms have become an important part of successful attraction and retention strategies and benefit from a regional approach to effectively cover all sectors. Many regions have thus become points of contact for prospective companies, talent and visitors.

Regional authorities are at the right scale to find the policy synergies and trade-offs that attractive policies entail. As the OECD attractiveness compass clearly shows, attractiveness policy is about enhancing synergies and addressing difficult trade-offs between different attractiveness levers and potentially contradictory individual objectives and targets. Across regions participating in the OECD Rethinking Regional Attractiveness project, such trade-offs have for instance been identified in relation to land use: between the expansion of industries and that of touristic activities, as well as between built land for industrial investment, housing and biodiversity preservation. Facilitating the consensual approach towards attractiveness priorities and strategies benefits from shared reference, such as the one proposed in the OECD regional attractiveness compass methodology. For the different stakeholders to converge in adopting shared objectives and strategies for the attractiveness of their region, it is also necessary to rely on dialogue and trust between the actors. Different types of mechanisms set up within the regions and with their partners can help, as described in this chapter. For instance, in a tripartite agreement, the regional government of the Balearic Islands (the Govern) together with the Balearic Islands Port Authority (which is a public body of Puertos del Estado, a public business entity dependent on the Spanish Ministry of Transport, Mobility and Urban Agenda and which manages the five ports of general interest of the Balearic Islands) and the Cruise Lines International Association (CLIA) have signed an agreement with the aim of regulating the arrival of tourism cruise ships in the city of Palma, which were negatively impacting biodiversity and local communities’ well-being. This agreement, which sets a maximum number of passengers and boats per day, is unique in the country and illustrates regions are well positioned to solve conflicts linked to attractiveness trade-offs (OECD, 2023[19]).

Effective multi-level co-ordination of regional attractiveness policies is necessary to avoid competition between areas in the same country. Regional authorities are well placed to design and implement attractiveness policies for their region, however not without the assistance of national governments and local authorities and actors. The diversity of initiatives at the regional level can lead to a lack of clarity and, to some extent, competition between regions. The lack of national initiative for attracting talent has for example led several regions in Sweden and elsewhere to feel compelled to launch their own initiatives, both for promotion and hosting, despite the limited money available and sometimes the lack of expertise. Such an approach risks duplication of effort, inconsistent external marketing and a lack of clarity and dispersion of the regional offer. Public resources are also wasted on creating similar parallel efforts and structures. As a result, regions in Denmark that felt they were becoming each other’s competitors in attracting talent instead of working for the best interests of Denmark came together to ask for national support and clear mandate. In 2019, a joint and co-ordinated national effort, called State of Denmark, was created. It aims to market the whole of Denmark as a career destination. Funding for these joint efforts is provided by the European Commission (European Social Fund, ESF) and the Danish government (Andersson, 2022[20]). The State of Denmark is, in turn, part of a larger public-private partnership called Talent to Denmark, within which 30 national organisations, such as Work in Denmark, regions, companies and networks, are included. Moreover, without national co-ordination, investment attractiveness strategies risk being at best barren. At worst, they can considerably aggravate territorial inequalities (Box 7.2). The state thus has a role to play in setting national guidelines and providing a system of arbitrage among regions to ensure that all regional attractiveness strategies comply with the overall national goals and that they do not generate zero-sum or pure waste competition.

Inclusive and resilient territorial attractiveness depends on quality public investment, especially in infrastructure, which requires good co-ordination between the different levels of government. Good quality and accessible railroads, roads and telecommunications, both within and leading to the region, are fundamental for attracting international targets. Investments in these physical infrastructures are among the most shared responsibilities between different levels of government and therefore require good co-ordination between them. For instance, subnational governments are generally responsible for local roads and transportation infrastructure, while higher levels of government generally manage investments with significant externalities. Vertical co-ordination mechanisms will help align objectives between all public stakeholders and bridge a series of information, financing and capacity gaps that impede efficient use of investment resources. As illustrated in Box 7.3 by the case of France’s ultra-high-speed broadband strategy (Plan très haut debit, PTHD), infrastructure investments co-ordinated at the national level can help reduce territorial inequalities, makes it possible to invest at the right scale, internalise the positive and negative impacts, and implement the complementary measures needed to make the most of public investment.

Unforeseen shocks with local impacts often require changes in the allocation of responsibilities and thereby effective intergovernmental co-ordination. This variability in the allocation of competencies over time and space requires a high degree of fluidity in the relationship between levels of government. For instance, while the COVID-19 pandemic was global in scale, its course and impacts differed across places – depending on local characteristics such as settlement density, mobility patterns, demography and economic activity. For example, compared to interior regions, the public finances of coastal regions in Italy and Spain suffered an intense blow due to travel restrictions and closure of hotels, thereby reducing tourist attendance, one of their main sources of subnational revenue (OECD/UCLG, 2022[2]). This pushed countries to change the distribution of competencies between different levels of government (OECD, 2022[26]). For instance, who was responsible for healthcare services varied a lot, with recentralisation being twice as frequent as decentralisation in OECD and partner countries (OECD, 2020[27]). Therefore, the pandemic put to the test countries’ multi-level governance frameworks. Highly decentralised systems were stressed by significant co-ordination challenges, while highly centralised systems experienced a lack of flexibility and room for manoeuvre to experiment and fight the pandemic consequences at the local level. In health terms, more decentralised health systems seem to have fared better during the pandemic (Rodríguez‐Pose and Burlina, 2021[28]; OECD, 2021[29]).

It re-emphasised that in all cases, pre-existent vertical co-operation mechanisms must exist so that, whatever the mode of governance and the policy area, it remains possible for all actors to carry out tasks, overcome obstacles and/or achieve shared objectives. This is important not only to enable adaptation and response to immediate needs arising from crises but also to ensure future capacity to do so and enhance the resilience of regions’ attractiveness.

In a context where good co-ordination is vital, governments have developed a wide range of mechanisms to help bridge information, capacity, fiscal, administrative or policy gaps between national and subnational governments. These mechanisms can range from “hard” to “soft” instruments. They include, for example, financial incentives to support co-operation between levels of government, co-financing mechanisms, joint investment strategies, the use of conditionalities in the allocation of funds, dialogue platforms or specific instruments such as contractual agreements (Box 7.4).

Regional public servants must have access to objective and subjective data at the most granular level possible and be data literate. If regional policy makers are to move beyond broad equity-efficiency, sustainability-efficiency or core-periphery perspectives to identify a fine-grained mix of policy and investment priorities relevant to specific places, they need to know what is happening on the ground and in all relevant sectors. Actions can involve, for example, complementing investment innovation support for firms in a region with measures to strengthen local capabilities and skills, and developing tertiary and vocational education to match enterprise demand (Ferry, 2021[34]). Regions also need in-depth data on their industries’ position in global value chains (GVCs) to identify their strengths and weaknesses and to pinpoint the specific support firms located in their territory need – in particular in terms of innovation and scaling. The local risk of industrial stagnation or “over-specialisation” also underscores the importance for public actors to hold the keys to help local industries diversify by attracting appropriate complementary investment and make the most of their interaction with research centres and universities. Finally, ensuring regional public servants have the capacity to collect and analyse subjective data, for instance through surveys or public consultations, is also crucial for policies’ relevance, political acceptance and social cohesion.

In a rapidly evolving world, not regularly revising policies to attract and retain talent, visitors and investors can lead to a quick deterioration in the relative attractiveness of a region – particularly if other regions with similar conditions are adopting policies flexible enough to adapt to changes and challenges. The global competition for mobile targets is growing with talent and multinational enterprises being increasingly able to choose the best destination for themselves. In this competitive environment, the position of regions constantly needs to be reassessed and attractiveness policies adapted accordingly. For instance, overlooking many regions’ efforts to succeed in their digital transition and the related increasing importance of access to high-speed Internet for talent and visitors will tomorrow discredit any attractiveness policy. The same is true of other global trends such as the green transition. This underlines the importance for regional governments to be able to actively update the policy framework in order to remain competitive and, therefore, have: i) strategic foresight capacities to anticipate systemic changes and quickly produce data; ii) solid co-ordination mechanisms allowing for frequent and easy consultations of all stakeholders; and iii) appropriate framework to navigate these changing waters with an “integrated information” compass, taking into account the diversity of attractiveness drivers, such as the one proposed in this report.

The capacity of regions to establish a dialogue with non-state actors, including civil society, is key. Where there is little capacity to co-design, jointly analyse the costs and benefits, and consult the public, there is a risk that policies will not achieve their objectives and may even have deleterious effects on residents and their perception of the benefits of globalisation (Arregui Coka and Rausch, 2020[35]). Regions must be able to develop and maintain regular contact and trust relationships with businesses, associations and overall civil society. This will improve the quality of policies, increase accountability, build trust in governments and help overcome potential opposition to policies as well as smooth and better understand “geographies of discontent”, directly linked to the increase in disparities between more dynamic, often metropolitan and less dynamic, often rural, territories (Dijkstra, Poelman and Rodríguez-Pose, 2020[36]). Trust relationships between public authorities, civil society and businesses are increasingly crucial to ensure the proper development of territories, in a context where many and varied “conflicts of use” emerge in relation to the different priorities of regional attractiveness and their local impact. For example, the decision to install a factory, a warehouse, a tourist or transport infrastructure, even if it provides jobs, cannot be implemented without the support of the population, which may fear the impact on the environment, particularly in terms of the use of water resources and the loss of biodiversity. This type of situation can lead to very localised tensions in terms of space allocation. Without a good relationship between the different actors and in view of the acceleration of climate change, the number of tensions is likely to increase. Regions must therefore be able to anticipate these localised challenges and put in place mechanisms for listening, consultation and collective decision making in terms of territorial attractiveness.

The challenges multi-level governance poses are characterised by the OECD as eight gaps to which public actors are invited to pay particular attention (Charbit, 2020[37]). This approach to characterise specific challenges of a variety of public policies is here adapted to regional attractiveness policies (OECD, 2022[38]). These issues are presented in Figure 7.1.

The OECD has developed a tool to provide policy makers suggestions and international examples to overcome the main gaps presented in Figure 7.1, which affect the ability of stakeholders involved in the development and implementation of attractiveness policies, to co-ordinate their activities (OECD, 2022[39]). It aims to support the dialogue between and the action of different actors across levels of government involved in regional attractiveness policies. It is, in effect, a roadmap to assess and respond to co-ordination challenges for regional attractiveness based on dialogue between stakeholders.

  • Self-assessment question: Is there a mechanism for information-sharing and converging the objectives of public decision-makers in terms of attractiveness?

  • Tools and methods to address this challenge

    • Developing institutional mappings of “who is doing what” to make sure all relevant actors are part of the discussion is the essential first step.

    • Strategic and regular committees for the coherence of local, regional, national (and European) strategies, with sufficient time for consultation and negotiation between the different stakeholders.

    • Contractual measures and/or conditionalities (e.g. green, social, strategic, etc.) regarding access to finance (Box 7.4)

  • Examples of good practice

    • Smart Specialisation Strategy Platform – S3/S4.1

    • In Ireland, a Network of Regional Skills Fora was created as part of the central government’s National Skills Strategy to provide a shared platform for actors in the regional education, employment and training sectors to work together to meet the skills and talent needs of the region.

    • The Danish co-ordination model for talent attraction, primarily because the regions, with support and funding from the national side, have built up a common model.

    • In the Community of Valencia in Spain, a Strategic Committee on Territorial Policy comprising regional authorities, civil society members and the private sector, aims to align the vision and priorities among the public and private sectors. This committee was established as part of the Territorial Governance strategy 2010-2030,2 whose objective is to develop innovative formulas of territorial governance and facilitate co-ordination among the three Valencian provinces. The strategy focuses on four pillars: i) public-private partnerships; ii) evaluation of policies and projects; iii) management and decision-making systems; and iv) accountability (OECD, 2023[10]).

    • In Centro, Portugal, the Schist Villages Network is part of the Programme for the Economic Enhancement of Endogenous Resources (PROVERE) and has established a platform for inter-municipal co-operation to foster effective communication between public and private entities (OECD, 2023[15]).

  • Self-assessment question: Are there common databases and tools for sharing information between different stakeholders?

  • Tools and methods to address this challenge

    • Agree on specific attractiveness indicators and then group the data produced on a shared regional platform, which will function as a “one-stop-shop for territorial data”.

    • Set up information desks to gather useful information between levels of government and private actors at a regional level (e.g. between regional government services, “deconcentrated” services – the regional representation of state agencies – representatives of civil society and local authorities).

    • Strengthen the presence and role of regional authorities in national discussions on attractiveness.

  • Examples of good practice

    • Regional data observatories (on employment, land, biodiversity, etc.):

      • The French National Agency for Territorial Cohesion’s Territorial Observatory and its interactive mapping site GEOT.3

      • Dataviz tool of the Banque des Territoires (for example: for the Territories of Industry,4 for the Cœur de Ville5 programme).

    • Information desks:

      • In Cantabria, Spain, the Digital Innovation Hub was created with the vision of becoming the point of reference for digital transformation in the region and serving as a meeting point between the supply and demand of technology, to unify access to resources for innovation and support the digitalisation of administrations and companies, with special attention to small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) and micro-SMEs. The hub aims to be part of the initiative Digitising European Industry, promoted by the European Commission.

      • Invest Lisboa, Portugal, is a one-stop-agency created through a partnership between the City Council and the Portuguese Chamber of Commerce to provide information and assist companies, investors and entrepreneurs looking to invest or set up their business in the city of Lisbon (OECD, 2023[7]).

  • Self-assessment question: What co-ordination mechanisms are in place to identify and take advantage of possible cross-sectoral synergies between several regional attractiveness and policies?

  • Tools and methods available to address this challenge

    • Inter-ministerial committees on country attractiveness involving representatives of infrastructure, environment, tourism, economy, social and territorial development, together with representatives of regional authorities.

    • Regional attractiveness committees for inclusive and sustainable development, involving representatives of local and national levels together with businesses and civil society representatives, considering all attractiveness targets (investors, talent and visitors) to identify priorities, synergies and trade-offs in their action.

    • Contractual measures encompassing different attractiveness policy fields to be dealt and monitored across levels of government.

  • Examples of good practice

    • In Spain, the Interterritorial Council for Internationalisation aims to serve as a permanent framework for collaboration between the different agents involved in the internationalisation process. Representatives from the autonomous communities, the Spanish Confederation of Business Organisations (CEOE), the Spanish Chamber of Commerce, the State Secretariat for Trade and the Spanish Institute of Foreign Trade (ICEX) aim to strengthen collaboration in the promotion of the internationalisation of Spanish companies and the attraction of investment to the country.

    • In Algarve, Portugal, the Regional Coordination and Development Commission (CCDR Algarve) is working to advance a multi-level governance model with the 16 municipalities to attract talent, investors and visitors. An integrated and intersectoral approach was put in place by the CCDR Algarve to co-ordinate the preparation of the Algarve 2030 Strategy and the Action Plan to Diversify Algarve, including close co-ordination with municipalities through the Intermunicipal Community of the Algarve (CIM-AMAL) (OECD, 2023[9]).

  • Self-assessment question: What are the human and technical capacities available to the regions for the implementation of attractiveness policies?

  • Tools and methods available to address this challenge

    • Management and staff mobility.

    • Language training and engineering support.

    • Sharing experiences between regions.

  • Examples of good practice

    • France’s ultra-high-speed broadband strategy (Plan très haut debit, PTHD) presented in Box 7.3 includes a budget for training civil servants to enable them to carry out their missions.

    • To support public administration, the Capacity Italy programme has been implemented to provide specialised expertise and technical assistance to public entities at all stages of the implementation of investments related to the National Recovery Plan, as well as the Capacity for Cohesion programme, to help public administrations manage European Union structural funds (OECD, 2023[40]).

  • Self-assessment question: Are all of the available funds mobilised by subnational authorities for the implementation of attractiveness and policies at the territorial level? Do the regions have sufficient financial resources to carry out the attractiveness policies that fall within their competency?

  • Tools and methods available to address this challenge

    • Contract schemes, including commitments or even financial transfers.

    • Mutual financial commitments (creation of own funds and participation of financial institutions).

  • Examples of good practice

    • New EU Territorial Cohesion Policy 2021-20276 and making budgets more flexible.

    • The financial and tax concessions supporting the attractiveness of Special Economic Zones in South Italy regions include national instruments co-financed by regional resources and instruments with direct regional competency financed through the European Regional Development Fund (ERDF) and ESF.

  • Self-assessment question: Is there a mechanism for assessing and assigning responsibility for attractiveness and internationalisation policies (including to the public)?

  • Tools and methods available to address this challenge

    • OECD recommendations for the implementation of a rigorous procedure for public policy evaluation (Box 4.4).

    • The OECD Recommendations on Open Government (OCDE, 2016[41]; 2017[42]).

    • Mobilising the European Quality Index (EQI)7 of subnational governments to promote regional attractiveness to investors and talent.

  • Examples of good practice

    • The OECD Observatory of Public Sector Innovation (OPSI).8

    • Strategic Committee (COSTRAT) for the attractiveness of the Grand Est Region in France, by crossing sectoral and territorial dimensions through the involvement of all stakeholders (OECD, 2022[39]).

  • Self-assessment question: Who are the private actors and civil society concerned by attractiveness policies? Have their opinions been incorporated into the design, implementation and evaluation of attractiveness policies? Do they participate in and help monitor regional attractiveness strategies?

  • Tools and methods available to address this challenge

    • Encourage citizen participation in the development, monitoring and evaluation of regional strategic plans and integrate the results into strategic documents.

    • Include in strategic documents actions to support the development and reinforcement of regional networks (arrangement of sponsorships, informal meetings for attractiveness actors, incentives for the development of multi-actor initiatives, etc.).

    • Invite land/logistics/tourism/academic actors to participate in existing discussions and contribute to strategic decisions on regional attractiveness. Consulting the following actors would benefit the quality of policies and the actors themselves:

      • Land actors: sustainable management of land resources (e.g. rehabilitation of brownfield sites) and development of economic land.

      • Logistics actors: strengthening the attractiveness of a regional industry.

      • Tourism actors: the attractiveness of the sector’s investors and researchers (via business tourism), the sustainable management of tourist flows and the emergence of new, more sustainable forms of tourism.

      • Academic actors: the attractiveness of talent in relation to regional innovation strategies and the development of new strategic GVCs.

  • Examples of good practice

    • The recovery strategy implemented by the Occitanie Region in France.9

    • The plan for the relocation and security of agri-food and health supplies in the Wallonia region of Belgium.10

    • The 2019 T-25 strategy in Norrbotten, Sweden, between employers and Luleå University, aimed at attracting 25 000 skilled workers over 5 years, notably by securing employment for spouses of recruits and by increasing graduate retention (OECD, 2023[16]).

    • The French Territoire d’Industrie11 programme and Team France Export involve the Chambers of Commerce and Industry, including during the monitoring and evaluation phases.

    • The province of Quebec, Canada, has developed a unique talent attraction model focused on international recruitment trips where delegations of employers travel to different target markets to attract candidates. These are managed operationally by the regional investment and development council, Quebec International (QI), with the support of the provincial government, the cities and municipalities, and the federal state.

  • Self-assessment question: Are there incentives to adopt policies at the right scale by involving those responsible for the various territories concerned in the definition and implementation of attractiveness policies and do they overcome rigid administrative boundaries?

  • Tools and methods available to address this challenge

    • Localised mapping (who are the actors in the territory and how do they interact with each other?).

    • Evaluation of positive and negative externalities from urban areas on neighbour rural places in the region.

    • Co-ordinated attractiveness strategies with neighbouring territories (territories of the same region, regions of the same country or border regions) to agree on shared objectives, investment priorities and the monitoring of related policies with indicators on territorial inequalities and their evolution.

  • Examples of good practice

    • Interreg European co-operation programmes.12

    • The project for common tourism in the Vanilla Islands.13

    • Visit Dalarna website and campaign putting forward regional assets to tourists and local ones (OECD, 2023[43]).

    • The Green Deal Site Visits, organised within the framework of the North Sweden Green Deal project by Region Norrbotten, Sweden, where students from Luleå University can visit each of the county’s municipalities for a day to make contacts and learn about work possibilities (OECD, 2023[16]).

    • In 2021, Portugal and Spain created a cross-border tourism sustainability strategy between them, containing tourism supply plans, mechanisms of governance and financing to make the measures effective, including the necessary participation of local entities, regions and autonomous communities. With the aim to dissociate the idea of the border as an area of transit, turning it into a unique, quality, not overcrowded destination that is, above all, authentic.

References

[20] Andersson, M. (2022), Talent Attraction Report for Sweden, Future Place Leadership.

[35] Arregui Coka, D. and T. Rausch (2020), Gains, Pains and Divides : Attitudes on the Eve of the Corona Crisis, Bertelsmann Stiftung, https://www.bertelsmann-stiftung.de/fileadmin/files/user_upload/MT_Globalization_Survey_2020_ENG.pdf.

[37] Charbit, C. (2020), “From ‘de jure’ to ‘de facto’ decentralised public policies: The multi-level governance approach”, The British Journal of Politics and International Relations, Vol. 22/4, pp. 809-819, https://doi.org/10.1177/1369148120937624.

[30] Charbit, C. and O. Romano (2017), “Governing together: An international review of contracts across levels of government for regional development”, OECD Regional Development Working Papers, No. 2017/04, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/ff7c8ac4-en.

[8] Diemer, A. et al. (2022), “The regional development trap in Europe”, Economic Geography, Vol. 98/5, pp. 487-509, https://doi.org/10.1080/00130095.2022.2080655.

[36] Dijkstra, L., H. Poelman and A. Rodríguez-Pose (2020), “The geography of EU discontent”, Regional Studies, Vol. 54/6, pp. 737-753, https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2019.1654603.

[34] Ferry, M. (2021), “Pulling things together: Regional policy coordination approaches and drivers in Europe”, Policy and Society, Vol. 40/1, pp. 37-57, https://doi.org/10.1080/14494035.2021.1934985.

[23] France Stratégie (2023), “Infrastructures numériques et aménagement du territoire : impacts économiques et sociaux du plan france très haut débit”.

[1] McNamara, M. (2012), “Starting to untangle the web of cooperation, coordination, and collaboration: A framework for public managers”, International Journal of Public Administration, Vol. 35/6, pp. 389-401, https://doi.org/10.1080/01900692.2012.655527.

[42] OCDE (2017), Recommandation du Conseil sur le Gouvernement Ouvert, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/gov/oecd-recommendation-of-the-council-on-open-government-fr.pdf.

[41] OCDE (2016), Le gouvernement ouvert : contexte mondiale et perspectives - Eléments clés, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/gov/Open-Government-Highlights-FR.pdf.

[4] OECD (2023), “Inter-municipal co-operation in the OECD: Opportunities and challenges for OECD countries – Preliminary insights from Finland, Lithuania and Estonia”.

[32] OECD (2023), “Les contrats entre niveaux de gouvernement: Un outil pour la régionalisation avancée au Maroc”, No. 48, Éditions OCDE, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/c29ad0fa-fr.

[33] OECD (2023), Les Régions dans le Nouvel Environnement Global : de la Crise à la Résilience. Le cas de Tanger-Tétouan-Al Hoceima, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/countries/morocco/les-regions-dans-le-nouvel-environnement-global-de-la-crise-a-la-resilience-le-cas-de-tanger.pdf.

[22] OECD (2023), “OECD webinar: Enhancing the attractiveness of non-Metropolitan Areas: The role of Special Economic Zones”, https://www.oecd.org/regional/globalisation.htm.

[3] OECD (2023), “Preliminary insights on implementing inter-municipal cooperation”, OECD, Paris.

[10] OECD (2023), Rethinking Regional Attractiveness in Spain’s Valencia Region, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/regional/globalisation.htm.

[9] OECD (2023), Rethinking Regional Attractiveness in the Algarve Region of Portugal, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/regional/globalisation.htm.

[19] OECD (2023), Rethinking Regional Attractiveness in the Balearic Islands Region of Spain, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/regional/rethinking-regional-attractiveness-in-the-balearic-islands-region-in-spain.pdf.

[15] OECD (2023), Rethinking Regional Attractiveness in the Centro Region of Portugal, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/regional/globalisation.htm.

[43] OECD (2023), Rethinking Regional Attractiveness in the Dalarna County of Sweden, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/regional/rethinking-regional-attractiveness-in-the-dalarna-country-of-sweden.pdf.

[18] OECD (2023), Rethinking Regional Attractiveness in the Italian Region of Campania, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/regional/globalisation.htm.

[40] OECD (2023), Rethinking Regional Attractiveness in the Italian Region of Marche, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/regional/rethinking-regional-attractiveness-in-the-italian-region-of-marche.pdf.

[7] OECD (2023), Rethinking Regional Attractiveness in the Metropolitan Area of Lisbon, Portugal, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/regional/globalisation.htm.

[16] OECD (2023), Rethinking Regional Attractiveness in the Norrbotten County of Sweden, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/regional/globalisation.htm.

[6] OECD (2023), Rethinking Regional Attractiveness in the Spanish region of Cantabria, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/regional/globalisation.htm.

[17] OECD (2023), The Future of Rural Manufacturing, OECD, Paris.

[26] OECD (2022), “Allocation of competences in policy sectors key to migrant integration: In a sample of ten OECD countries”, OECD Regional Development Papers, No. 25, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/dc4a71c5-en.

[39] OECD (2022), L’internationalisation et l’attractivité des régions françaises, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/6f04564a-fr.

[38] OECD (2022), “Multi-level governance for migrant integration: Policy instruments from Austria, Canada, France, Germany and Italy”, OECD Regional Development Papers, No. 24, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/efeeda9d-en.

[11] OECD (2022), Regional Governance in OECD Countries: Trends, Typology and Tools, OECD Multi-level Governance Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/4d7c6483-en.

[21] OECD (2022), “The geography of foreign investment in OECD member countries: How investment promotion agencies support regional development”, OECD Business and Finance Policy Papers, No. 20, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/1f293a25-en.

[29] OECD (2021), “The territorial impact of COVID-19: Managing the crisis and recovery across levels of government”, OECD Policy Responses to Coronavirus (COVID-19), OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/coronavirus/policy-responses/the-territorial-impact-of-covid-19-managing-the-crisis-and-recovery-across-levels-of-government-a2c6abaf/.

[27] OECD (2020), “COVID-19 and fiscal relations across levels of government”, OECD Policy Responses to Coronavirus (COVID-19), OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/coronavirus/policy-responses/covid-19-and-fiscal-relations-across-levels-of-government-ab438b9f/.

[12] OECD (2020), The Future of Regional Development and Public Investment in Wales, United Kingdom, OECD Multi-level Governance Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/e6f5201d-en.

[25] OECD (2019), Effective Multi-level Public Investment, OECD, Paris.

[24] OECD (2019), Making Decentralisation Work: A Handbook for Policy-Makers, OECD Multi-level Governance Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/g2g9faa7-en.

[14] OECD (2016), OECD Regional Outlook 2016: Productive Regions for Inclusive Societies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264260245-en.

[31] OECD (2007), Linking Regions and Central Governments: Contracts for Regional Development, OECD, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/gov/linkingregionsandcentralgovernmentscontractsforregionaldevelopment.htm.

[5] OECD (forthcoming), Rural-urban Linkages in the New Spatial Equilibrium, OECD Publishing, Paris.

[2] OECD/UCLG (2022), 2022 Report of the World Observatory on Subnational Government Finance and Investment – Key Findings.

[28] Rodríguez‐Pose, A. and C. Burlina (2021), “Institutions and the uneven geography of the first wave of the COVID‐19 pandemic”, Journal of Regional Science, Vol. 61/4, pp. 728-752, https://doi.org/10.1111/jors.12541.

[13] Welsh Government (2019), Prosperity for All: Economic Action Plan.

Metadata, Legal and Rights

This document, as well as any data and map included herein, are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. Extracts from publications may be subject to additional disclaimers, which are set out in the complete version of the publication, available at the link provided.

© OECD 2023

The use of this work, whether digital or print, is governed by the Terms and Conditions to be found at https://www.oecd.org/termsandconditions.