Vietnam

There is virtually no land value capture in Vietnam (Table 2.60). The government uses public land lease only, but corruption hampers it. Many challenges block land value capture:

  • Public actions’ low transparency and high land values incentivise government officials to use land value capture for private rather than public benefit.

  • There is no legislation for land value capture. Development norms and regulations are unclear.

  • Many urban areas’ cadastres are not up to date, inaccurate or incomplete.

  • There is no established method to value land. The government uses a combination of prices set by government agencies and some market-based estimation.

  • Local governments lack administrative capacity.

  • According to Article 32 of the Constitution, the government can only expropriate land when absolutely necessary for reasons of national defence, security, national interest, emergency and protection against natural calamities.

Vietnam is a unitary state with three subnational levels of government: 63 provinces, 713 districts and 11,162 municipalities (OECD/UCLG, 2019[1]). Districts and municipalities are the planning authorities and decide on land use and management. Local officials have high discretion when issuing planning permits. The national and local government levels would be in charge of the legal framework for land value capture.

The government and publicly-owned companies own a large amount of land. The national government, provinces, districts, local governments and special purpose bodies lease public land (cho thuê đất công) to generate revenues, provide land for real estate development and encourage planned development as well as development with a public purpose. Subnational governments may require approval from higher levels. The revenues are part of the general budget of the entities leasing land. In 2017, lease revenues amounted to 3% of GDP.

However, corruption hampers the instrument. Often, the government used to lease land to private developers in exchange for public infrastructure. However, the leased land did not necessarily have to relate to the public infrastructure the developers provided. Thus, developers had no incentive to provide the agreed infrastructure on time and with a high quality. Moreover, land valuation is not transparent. In 2020, the national government banned leasing public land in exchange for public infrastructure to tackle corruption.

Other challenges include the government’s lack of administrative capacity as well as the lack of coordination between levels of government and public entities.

References

[3] OECD (2022), “Subnational government structure and finance”, OECD Regional Statistics (database), https://doi.org/10.1787/05fb4b56-en (accessed on 13 January 2022).

[8] OECD (2021), “Subnational government structure and finance”, OECD Regional Statistics (database), https://doi.org/10.1787/05fb4b56-en (accessed on 25 November 2021).

[2] OECD (2017), Land-use Planning Systems in the OECD: Country Fact Sheets, OECD Regional Development Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264268579-en.

[1] OECD/UCLG (2019), 2019 Report of the World Observatory on Subnational Government Finance and Investment - Country Profiles, OECD/UCLG.

Metadata, Legal and Rights

This document, as well as any data and map included herein, are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. Extracts from publications may be subject to additional disclaimers, which are set out in the complete version of the publication, available at the link provided.

© OECD/Lincoln Institute of Land Policy 2022.

The use of this work, whether digital or print, is governed by the Terms and Conditions to be found at https://www.oecd.org/termsandconditions.